Announcement

Collapse
No announcement yet.

Fracting Labor

Collapse
X
 
  • Filter
  • Time
  • Show
Clear All
new posts

  • Fracting Labor

    By Robert Kuttner

    The Fissured Workplace: Why Work Became So Bad For So Many and What Can Be Done to Improve It

    by David Weil
    Harvard University Press, 410 pp., $29.95

    Private Equity at Work: When Wall Street Manages Main Street

    by Eileen Appelbaum and Rosemary Batt
    Russell Sage Foundation, 381 pp., $35.00 (paper)

    In the past generation, there has been a drastic change in how work is organized. Regular payroll employment is becoming the exception. The employer of record is no longer the corporation, but a web of intermediaries. The outside contractor demands stringent worker performance, even as it drives down wages, job security, and benefits.

    David Weil writes in his authoritative new book, The Fissured Workplace:

    As major companies have consciously invested in building brands and devoted customers as the cornerstone of their business strategy, they have also shed their role as the direct employer of the people responsible for providing those products and services.

    This system, which began in peripheral occupations such as janitors or security guards, has become pervasive. FedEx workers wear the company’s uniforms, drive its trucks, and adhere to stringent rules; but they are independent contractors, not company employees. At many leading hotels, room cleaners and desk clerks actually work for management companies, not for Marriott or Hilton. The technician sent by Comcast to fix your cable may well be a freelancer, not an employee. When you go into a government building, the receptionist/guard is likely not a civil servant, but the low-wage hire of a security firm. That firm, in turn, is likely to be owned by a private equity company. Apple employs some 63,000 workers directly, and more than 750,000 in a variety of contract relationships. When horrific working conditions were revealed in a Chinese plant that made iPhones and iPads, Apple—one of the world’s most exacting companies when it comes to technical quality—could blame the contractor.

    By “fissured,” Weil means fragmented, as in the fissuring of a rock or an atom. The term may strike some readers as an odd usage, but the metaphor is exact. Weil points out that the fissuring mechanisms include not just the familiar categories of temp and part-timer, but “subcontracting, franchising, third-party management, outsourcing” that allow a corporation to fragment employment yet maintain standards.

    Half a century ago, at the peak of the postwar boom, large employers took direct responsibility for their workers. Today, Weil reports, about one worker in three is hired not by the corporation identified with the product but by someone else, and the connection between employer and employee is fractured. Large corporations “have it both ways,” Weil writes:

    While a major restaurant brand may set out standards and guidelines that dictate to a minute degree the way that food is prepared, presented, and served, and specify cleaning routines, schedules, and even the products to be used, it would recoil from being held responsible for franchisees’ failure to provide overtime pay for workers, for curbing sexual harassment of workers by supervisors, or for reducing exposure to dangerous cleaning materials.

    This new system frees corporations from the obligations of a tacit social compact in which employee loyalty is reciprocated, companies have an incentive to invest in workers, and people can look forward to predictable careers. Moreover, the entire structure of worker protections and benefits legislated beginning in the New Deal is predicated on the assumption that the employee is on the payroll of the company that makes the product.1 A casual worker has fewer rights, and those that carry over are harder to enforce. A contract worker or temp pays his or her own Social Security taxes, can seldom collect unemployment compensation, rarely receives company-provided health insurance or pension benefits, and has scant opportunity to organize or join a union. Such workers are more likely to experience wage theft, sub-minimum wages, overtime violations, working conditions that violate health and safety laws—and have less practical recourse to legal remedies. “The modern employment relationship,” Weil writes, “bears little resemblance to that assumed in our core workplace regulations.”

    How did “fissuring” become the new employment norm, and why do workers accept it? Weil cites two main factors. First, “capital markets demanded it,” as investors and traders gained power over managers in the era of financial deregulation that began roughly in 1980. Second, new technologies created new ways “of designing and monitoring the work of other parties,” making it easier to outsource work while retaining and even intensifying control over worker performance.

    Yet this is primarily a story of shifting political power. Long before the digital economy, employers regularly sought to lower labor costs by turning payroll employment into casual work. Weil recounts a 1902 strike of 30,000 Italian immigrant workers hired to build New York’s first subway. The prime city contract was held by a bankers’ syndicate, which in turn used padroni to recruit and pay laborers. The workers, savvy about the dynamics of pay and power, were striking to be paid as employees directly by the syndicate, and not as casual labor by middlemen.

    Similarly, in the garment industry, for more than a century employers have undercut wages by contracting work via outside middlemen known as jobbers. The subcontracting forced workers to compete with one another over who could offer the lowest piece rates.4 Only during the peak influence of garment workers’ unions was this system rejected in favor of direct payroll employment. These struggles had nothing to do with technology and everything to do with power.

    Weil is right, however, that the latest round of work degradation was set off by financial deregulation. The extreme case is the private equity industry. Economists Eileen Appelbaum and Rosemary Batt provide a comprehensive examination of this shadowy sector in Private Equity at Work: When Wall Street Manages Main Street. Though the authors concentrate on work and workers, they offer a thorough exploration of how private equity operates by explaining how actual businesses are financed, as well as producing extensive data. Their sources range from regulatory filings and court records, econometric analyses, and the business school literature, to their own original interviews and case studies. Their book can be read as a complement to Weil’s, because it explains how the business strategies of these investment companies logically destroy and degrade jobs, not for economic efficiency or better management but to transfer wealth from workers to financial engineers.

    Private equity is a sly misnomer—a rebranding of what used to be called leveraged buyouts (LBOs) or, more coarsely, corporate raids. When raiders began the practice of purchasing majority control in a company using borrowed money collateralized by the target company’s own assets, some federal and state regulators wondered if such so-called “tender offers” were legal, but quickly acceded to the anything-goes ethic of the 1980s. The sponsors (general partners) of a private equity company seldom contribute net equity capital like their distant cousins, venture capitalists. Mainly, they incur debt, invariably collateralized by the assets of the target company itself.

    Contrary to the industry’s claims about being experts in turning companies from losers to winners, private equity typically targets healthy companies rather than underperforming ones, the better to extract cash reserves. Having loaded the balance sheet of the company with debt—debt incurred in the purchase of that very company—they hire managers to run as lean and ruthless an operation as possible. They borrow even more money to pay themselves “special dividends,” to recoup their initial small equity outlay many times over even if the operating company goes broke. The big losers in this game are the company’s workers.

    In case studies, Applebaum and Batt describe how the general partners of a private equity firm strip assets and extract money from the target company, leaving it hobbled with debt. Private equity executives further enrich themselves by charging the company management fees. Since so many target companies eventually go broke after the private equity engineers cash out, it’s impossible to know how much better conventional ownership might have done, but it could hardly have done worse.

    When Bain Capital took over KB Toys in 2000, it put up just 6 percent and borrowed the rest using KB Toys’ assets as collateral. Before KB went bankrupt, costing ten thousand jobs, Bain realized a gain of 360 percent on its original investment. Sun Capital, purchaser of the ice cream chain Friendly’s, loaded the company with debt, extracted dividends, laid off workers, and took Friendly’s into bankruptcy. But then “a second Sun Capital affiliate announced its intention to acquire the restaurant chain. A third Sun Capital unit came forward to provide a loan to finance the chain’s operations while it was in bankruptcy.” Such maneuvers enabled Sun to strip assets from the operating company and shed debts including pension obligations—yet retain control.

    Appelbaum and Batt are scrupulously fair in reporting the exceptional cases where private equity firms do contribute to the successful rescue of failing or underperforming companies. But even in these instances, the divisions of the spoils are often revealing. In one such case, the investment banker Wilbur Ross, a man with a reputation for working with unions, joined forces with the United Steelworkers in 2002 to buy several shuttered steel mills out of bankruptcy. Ross persuaded the unions to cut wages and benefits, and restored the mills to profitability.

    Ross himself contributed only $90 million in cash; the rest of the multibillion-dollar purchase and upgrading was financed by debt and investment capital contributed by limited partners. Thousands of jobs were saved at reduced wages, but when Ross cashed out in 2005, his personal profit was fourteen times the money he’d invested. Appelbaum and Batt note that “his three year investment netted him $4.5 billion—just equal to what retirees lost in their health and pension plans.”

    Ross’s story, it should be made clear, is private equity at its best. More typical are the dozens of cases recounted by the authors where private equity has no interest in preserving a potentially profitable company or workers’ jobs, but simply seeks to extract as much profit as quickly as possible.

    Because private equity firms are not publicly traded on stock exchanges, they escape most of the system’s regulatory requirements. The securities regulations dating to 1933 are premised on the assumption that disclosures are needed to protect investors. But since private equity companies are not traded on the market, they are exempt. However, these firms do in fact sell shares to investors, who are technically considered “limited partners,” thus evading disclosure requirements.

    Since the general partners of private equity firms make such outsized returns, investors want a piece of that action. But Appelbaum and Batt cite data showing that most of the returns to limited partners do not beat the performance of the S&P 500. Even more peculiar is the fact that some 35 percent of the investment capital put up by limited partners comes from pension funds—which represent the deferred wages of workers. So workers’ own funds become part of the financial system that drives down workers’ wages and often plunders other pension systems.

    While new technology does not explain the rupture of the old social compact, it does facilitate the shift to an economy of casual work. Elements of the new digital economy are well suited to fissuring. Many corporations in Silicon Valley like to think of themselves as “virtual,” not engaged in direct hiring or direct management of services or product sales. Some billion-dollar start-ups have fewer than a hundred salaried employees. Web-based companies such as Uber (an application that links passengers to part-time drivers) or Airbnb (which connects short-term landlords to tourists) or TaskRabbit (a matching service for odd jobs) reflect an economy in which more and more people feel like freelancers.

    The insecurity of the new labor market gets internalized in the expectations of young workers. If there are few regular jobs out there, one might as well make the best of it. If your Web start-up fails, there is always work as a temp. On the other hand, if macroeconomic policy produced something closer to full employment and national policy favored regularized employment, fewer college graduates would have to enlist as TaskRabbits or Uber drivers.

    In fact, for reasons unrelated to education or technology, a great many jobs can be configured either as casual labor or as normal payroll employment. In many states, for example, home health aides are individual contractors with low wages and insecure employment to match. But in states with strong unions such as California, home health aides have won the right to form bargaining units and are compensated as payroll employees. Warehouse workers for Walmart are hired and employed by logistics contractors; they are low-paid, and subject to arbitrary dismissal. Elsewhere, however, many warehouse workers are salaried employees and receive middle-class compensation.

    In cities with strong hotel unions such as New York and Las Vegas, hotel employees are salaried and receive good wages and benefits. The union successfully resists management’s efforts to turn employees into “on-call” casual labor. In other cities, hotel workers performing the same jobs for the same brands work at barely more than minimum wage, often for contractors who supply personnel. The general trend to lower-paid work has little to do with education, technology, or management “efficiency.” It is a pure transfer from labor to capital.

    Weil, Appelbaum, and Batt are accomplished technical economists. They belong to an economics tradition known as institutionalism, one that pays close attention to economic history, organizational forms, and changing political power; yet these authors also display mastery of a wide range of economic data. Like the workplace, today’s economics profession is fissured. Those who explore inequality by emphasizing education and technology, while paying no attention to the drastically altered social contract that is now becoming dominant, are missing much of the story.

  • #2
    Re: Fracting Labor

    Thanks, don. Well worth reading.

    Comment


    • #3
      Re: Fracting Labor

      Impotent Labor = All-Powerful Capital

      Bad news for most of us.

      Comment


      • #4
        Re: Fracting Labor

        They call it "capitalism" for something; don't they?

        Comment


        • #5
          Re: Fracting Labor

          If we can't extend wages, thankfully we can at least remove (err, redirect) the risks of extending debt...

          Fannie, Freddie Near Deal to Boost Mortgage Lending: Accord Gives Banks More Protection Against Charges of Making Bad Loans
          Mortgage giants Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac , their regulator and lenders are close to an agreement that could greatly expand mortgage credit while helping lenders protect themselves from charges of making bad loans, according to people familiar with the matter.

          Comment


          • #6
            Re: Fracting Labor

            Actually they now call it "the free market". Calling it capitalism, or more accurately monopoly capitalism (the anathema of free competition), is verboten.

            Comment


            • #7
              Re: Fracting Labor

              Originally posted by don View Post
              Actually they now call it "the free market". Calling it capitalism, or more accurately monopoly capitalism (the anathema of free competition), is verboten.
              Right: the term "capitalism" is verboten nowadays. Too transparent. As of "monoply capitalism" there is a permanent tension between "free markets" and monopoly. Monopoly is in reality in the pure origins of capitalism. Remember the "companies of the Indias" or whatever they were called by England, Spain, Holland or France in the times when capitalism was still fighting against the remnants of feudalism. It was a pure state controlled monopolistic form of the system. At the same time there was, and shall always will be, competition. Apple and Samsung have some sort of duopoly in the smartphone business. They, however compete between them and with other menacing companies.
              Of course, capitalists are always looking for rentier benefits. The example is in public services sectors and the fierce battle to privatize them. At first sight I tend to think that the predominance of one form (free market) or the other (competence) evolves in waves as time goes.

              Comment


              • #8
                Re: Fracting Labor

                Agree with the above, with a few caveats. Monopoly capitalism in the modern sense, over the last 100 years, is one of continuing concentration, which led to the 1950s version, oligopolies no longer competing in self-defeating price wars but over market shares, which heralded the explosion of advertising. Main street will always be competitive, albeit over its ever-shrinking slice of the pie. The high productivity of the M-C enterprises led to a crisis of overproduction, buffered first by ever larger advertising budgets, and when that proved inadequate for capital investment, the financialization of the economy. A corollary is the capture of government by the M-C corporations. That's the macro environment we find ourselves in. We just have to make the best of it.

                Comment


                • #9
                  Re: Fracting Labor

                  It would be interesting to get EJ's take on whether entrepreneur activity and venture capital can erode concentration in various industries in the current environment. Will new technologies allow newer companies to reduce the influence of large companies and change the dynamics of industries?

                  Also aren't large enterprises necessary in a global economy? You either have a lot of large, a lot of medium, and many smaller companies. Or you have state owned industries, which are themselves the worst form of monopoly.


                  https://www.secondmarket.com/educati...eport_2013.pdf

                  http://www.kauffman.org/~/media/kauf...is%20us(1).pdf
                  Last edited by vt; October 18, 2014, 04:27 PM.

                  Comment


                  • #10
                    Re: Fracting Labor

                    In most cases the best hope of new technology entrepreneurs is to be bought up by a M-C corporation. That's the Big Win, the best they can most often hope for.

                    Comment


                    • #11
                      Re: Fracting Labor

                      Originally posted by don View Post
                      In most cases the best hope of new technology entrepreneurs is to be bought up by a M-C corporation. That's the Big Win, the best they can most often hope for.
                      Someone mentioned this geat article The most expensive lottery ticket in the world on iTulip in the past. And then there's Corporate America Hasn't Been Disrupted.

                      Comment


                      • #12
                        Michael Hudson




                        IMF Meeting Review – Austerity to Cost

                        Comment


                        • #13
                          Re: Fracting Labor

                          Harry Braverman's Labor and Monopoly Capital is the seminal work on this question.

                          Harry Braverman’s Labor and Monopoly Capital, first published forty
                          years ago in 1974, was unquestionably the work that, in the words of
                          historian Bryan Palmer, “literally christened the emerging field of labor
                          process studies.”1 In the four decades since its appearance Braverman’s
                          book has continued to play a central role in debates on workers’
                          struggles within industry, remaining indispensable to all attempts at
                          in-depth critique in this area. On Labor Day 2009, in the midst of the
                          Great Recession, the Wall Street Journal declared Labor and Monopoly Capital
                          to be number one among the “Five Best Books on Working.”

                          In February 1975, Braverman presented an extended talk, entitled
                          “The Making of the U.S. Working Class,” at Empire State College in
                          New York. Significantly, the organization of that talk inverted the
                          ordering of the argument in Labor and Monopoly Capital. It started with
                          what had been his overarching question all along: “What do we mean
                          by working class?” Avoiding facile definitions but concentrating rather
                          on the historical processes and objective determinants, he commenced
                          the analysis by looking at the major occupational groupings of the
                          working class and how this changed from the nineteenth century to the
                          twentieth century. Only then did he proceed to the labor process under
                          the regime of monopoly capital, extrapolating from those tendencies
                          the development of new occupational structures and the further evolution
                          of the working class—taking into account also such issues as
                          automation, the growth of the reserve army of labor, and the increasing
                          employment of labor in socially wasteful and unproductive spheres
                          such as real estate, insurance, and finance.

                          Governing much of Braverman’s analysis in Labor and Monopoly Capital
                          itself was the recognition that portions of what had been referred to by
                          earlier sociological theorists such as Lewis Corey and C. Wright Mills as
                          the “new middle class,” comprising the disparate white-collar sector—
                          stretching all the way from secretaries and sales clerks to managers and
                          professionals—would increasingly be brought under the capitalist labor
                          process. With the “degradation” of their work and pay structures, they
                          would simply merge with the blue-collar workers. Corey had perceived
                          this tendency at an early stage, arguing that “the mechanization of clerical
                          labor becomes constantly greater; a typical large office is now nothing
                          but a white-collar factory.”

                          For Braverman the new occupational sectors, originally associated
                          with higher skills and higher status—and with a “new middle
                          class” of salaried workers—were themselves being subjected in turn
                          to the relentless degradation of their working conditions, and thus
                          integration with the old, production-based working class. Specifically,
                          he sought to understand the evolution of what he called capitalism’s
                          “growing working-class occupations,” rising out of the conditions of
                          monopoly capital: clerical labor and service-sector workers.

                          An indication of how far the white-collar occupations have
                          subsided is that the very “term white collar,” as Russell Jacoby points
                          out, “has fallen into relative disuse…. ‘White-collar’ surfaces” in academic
                          discourse today “mainly in connection to white-collar crime,
                          where it has become a catch-all for nonviolent offenses.” So clearly are
                          the bulk of white-collar employees now working rather than middle class
                          that this whole distinction, which was tied to the notion of the “new
                          middle class,” has lost most of its meaning. Similarly in the scholarly
                          literature “blue collar” is usually referred to only when discussing the
                          relative decline of this segment of the working class in relation to the
                          growing segments of clerical, service, and sales workers. Although the
                          inclusion of clerical and sales workers in the working class was still
                          fairly contentious when Braverman was writing, today it is taken for
                          granted in sociological studies.

                          Today, the notion of the middle class and even upper-middle class
                          as stable, secure, propertied, and solidifying elements of the population
                          has so eroded, that the Occupy movement’s critique of the 1%—which
                          highlighted the growing polarization of U.S. society between a relatively
                          small capitalist class and its hangers-on and the rest of the population—
                          was immediately embraced by the vast majority of the U.S. population.
                          This reflects the fact that the United States now has the most unequal
                          distribution of wealth of all the advanced economies—an inequality
                          that is greater than that of India and South Africa.41 Under these circumstances
                          the myth of the United States as a “middle-class society”

                          stabilized by a large intermediate strata is eroding rapidly.
                          In Braverman’s terms this relatively small intermediate layer—
                          since the lower white-collar occupations in clerical, service, and sales
                          were shown to be working class—consisted mostly of “the engineering,
                          technical, and scientific cadre, the lower ranks of supervision and
                          management, the considerable numbers of specialized and ‘professional’
                          employees occupied in marketing, financial and organizational
                          administration, and the like, as well as, outside of capitalist industry
                          proper [workers] in hospitals, schools, government administration
                          and so forth.”

                          This “privileged intermediate strata in professional
                          occupations and in middle management” had been brought into
                          being, he contended, by the development of monopoly capitalism and
                          its relentless process of “rationalization.” The economy of the giant
                          corporations generated what was called a “managerial revolution”
                          leading to the expansion of managerial, financial, marketing, media,
                          and state professionals in order to: (1) control the labor process; (2)
                          enlarge the propensity to consume; (3) run a growing financial superstructure;
                          (4) manage public opinion; and (5) provide public-spending
                          supports to private corporations and relief work on behalf of the general
                          population (itself a vital subsidy to capital, which was then not
                          compelled to pay the full cost of the reproduction of labor power).

                          Although Braverman recognized the importance of the intermediate
                          strata to the functioning of monopoly capitalism, he also saw this
                          and other developments within capitalism as dynamic and subject to
                          change. Indeed, “classes, the class structure, the social structure as a
                          whole,” he wrote, “are not fixed entities but rather ongoing processes,
                          rich in change, transition, variation.” The intermediate layer of the new
                          middle class brought into being by monopoly capitalism would eventually,
                          he believed, succumb in large part to the same general forces that
                          had broken down skilled labor, creating a more homogenous general
                          work force—although this tendency was subject to various countervailing
                          forces.

                          Braverman’s famous analysis of the degradation of work in Labor
                          and Monopoly Capital was only one of three trends with respect to labor
                          (outside of the changing occupational structure of the working class
                          itself) that he saw as characterizing the advanced monopoly-capitalist
                          economy. The other two being the growth of unemployment and
                          underemployment (associated with economic stagnation), and the
                          increasing growth of wasteful or socially unproductive employment.

                          What sort of unproductive labors? Let me give you these examples: the
                          banking, the insurance, the investment [financial], the brokerage, the real
                          estate industries; the advertising and other marketing industries; the
                          accounting and control industries, including those operated by the government
                          in the form of regulatory or tax agencies; the relief industries,
                          such as those which deal with unemployment compensation or welfare….

                          Comment


                          • #14
                            Re: Fracting Labor

                            Harry Braverman's Labor and Monopoly Capital is a seminal work on this question.

                            Harry Braverman’s Labor and Monopoly Capital, first published forty
                            years ago in 1974, was unquestionably the work that, in the words of
                            historian Bryan Palmer, “literally christened the emerging field of labor
                            process studies.”1 In the four decades since its appearance Braverman’s
                            book has continued to play a central role in debates on workers’
                            struggles within industry, remaining indispensable to all attempts at
                            in-depth critique in this area. On Labor Day 2009, in the midst of the
                            Great Recession, the Wall Street Journal declared Labor and Monopoly Capital
                            to be number one among the “Five Best Books on Working.”

                            In February 1975, Braverman presented an extended talk, entitled
                            “The Making of the U.S. Working Class,” at Empire State College in
                            New York. Significantly, the organization of that talk inverted the
                            ordering of the argument in Labor and Monopoly Capital. It started with
                            what had been his overarching question all along: “What do we mean
                            by working class?” Avoiding facile definitions but concentrating rather
                            on the historical processes and objective determinants, he commenced
                            the analysis by looking at the major occupational groupings of the
                            working class and how this changed from the nineteenth century to the
                            twentieth century. Only then did he proceed to the labor process under
                            the regime of monopoly capital, extrapolating from those tendencies
                            the development of new occupational structures and the further evolution
                            of the working class—taking into account also such issues as
                            automation, the growth of the reserve army of labor, and the increasing
                            employment of labor in socially wasteful and unproductive spheres
                            such as real estate, insurance, and finance.

                            Governing much of Braverman’s analysis in Labor and Monopoly Capital
                            itself was the recognition that portions of what had been referred to by
                            earlier sociological theorists such as Lewis Corey and C. Wright Mills as
                            the “new middle class,” comprising the disparate white-collar sector—
                            stretching all the way from secretaries and sales clerks to managers and
                            professionals—would increasingly be brought under the capitalist labor
                            process. With the “degradation” of their work and pay structures, they
                            would simply merge with the blue-collar workers. Corey had perceived
                            this tendency at an early stage, arguing that “the mechanization of clerical
                            labor becomes constantly greater; a typical large office is now nothing
                            but a white-collar factory.”

                            For Braverman the new occupational sectors, originally associated
                            with higher skills and higher status—and with a “new middle
                            class” of salaried workers—were themselves being subjected in turn
                            to the relentless degradation of their working conditions, and thus
                            integration with the old, production-based working class. Specifically,
                            he sought to understand the evolution of what he called capitalism’s
                            “growing working-class occupations,” rising out of the conditions of
                            monopoly capital: clerical labor and service-sector workers.

                            An indication of how far the white-collar occupations have
                            subsided is that the very “term white collar,” as Russell Jacoby points
                            out, “has fallen into relative disuse…. ‘White-collar’ surfaces” in academic
                            discourse today “mainly in connection to white-collar crime,
                            where it has become a catch-all for nonviolent offenses.” So clearly are
                            the bulk of white-collar employees now working rather than middle class
                            that this whole distinction, which was tied to the notion of the “new
                            middle class,” has lost most of its meaning. Similarly in the scholarly
                            literature “blue collar” is usually referred to only when discussing the
                            relative decline of this segment of the working class in relation to the
                            growing segments of clerical, service, and sales workers. Although the
                            inclusion of clerical and sales workers in the working class was still
                            fairly contentious when Braverman was writing, today it is taken for
                            granted in sociological studies.

                            Today, the notion of the middle class and even upper-middle class
                            as stable, secure, propertied, and solidifying elements of the population
                            has so eroded, that the Occupy movement’s critique of the 1%—which
                            highlighted the growing polarization of U.S. society between a relatively
                            small capitalist class and its hangers-on and the rest of the population—
                            was immediately embraced by the vast majority of the U.S. population.
                            This reflects the fact that the United States now has the most unequal
                            distribution of wealth of all the advanced economies—an inequality
                            that is greater than that of India and South Africa.41 Under these circumstances
                            the myth of the United States as a “middle-class society”

                            stabilized by a large intermediate strata is eroding rapidly.
                            In Braverman’s terms this relatively small intermediate layer—
                            since the lower white-collar occupations in clerical, service, and sales
                            were shown to be working class—consisted mostly of “the engineering,
                            technical, and scientific cadre, the lower ranks of supervision and
                            management, the considerable numbers of specialized and ‘professional’
                            employees occupied in marketing, financial and organizational
                            administration, and the like, as well as, outside of capitalist industry
                            proper [workers] in hospitals, schools, government administration
                            and so forth.”

                            This “privileged intermediate strata in professional
                            occupations and in middle management” had been brought into
                            being, he contended, by the development of monopoly capitalism and
                            its relentless process of “rationalization.” The economy of the giant
                            corporations generated what was called a “managerial revolution”
                            leading to the expansion of managerial, financial, marketing, media,
                            and state professionals in order to: (1) control the labor process; (2)
                            enlarge the propensity to consume; (3) run a growing financial superstructure;
                            (4) manage public opinion; and (5) provide public-spending
                            supports to private corporations and relief work on behalf of the general
                            population (itself a vital subsidy to capital, which was then not
                            compelled to pay the full cost of the reproduction of labor power).

                            Although Braverman recognized the importance of the intermediate
                            strata to the functioning of monopoly capitalism, he also saw this
                            and other developments within capitalism as dynamic and subject to
                            change. Indeed, “classes, the class structure, the social structure as a
                            whole,” he wrote, “are not fixed entities but rather ongoing processes,
                            rich in change, transition, variation.” The intermediate layer of the new
                            middle class brought into being by monopoly capitalism would eventually,
                            he believed, succumb in large part to the same general forces that
                            had broken down skilled labor, creating a more homogenous general
                            work force—although this tendency was subject to various countervailing
                            forces.

                            Braverman’s famous analysis of the degradation of work in Labor
                            and Monopoly Capital was only one of three trends with respect to labor
                            (outside of the changing occupational structure of the working class
                            itself) that he saw as characterizing the advanced monopoly-capitalist
                            economy. The other two being the growth of unemployment and
                            underemployment (associated with economic stagnation), and the
                            increasing growth of wasteful or socially unproductive employment.

                            What sort of unproductive labors? Let me give you these examples: the
                            banking, the insurance, the investment [financial], the brokerage, the real
                            estate industries; the advertising and other marketing industries; the
                            accounting and control industries, including those operated by the government
                            in the form of regulatory or tax agencies; the relief industries,
                            such as those which deal with unemployment compensation or welfare….

                            Comment

                            Working...
                            X