Announcement

Collapse
No announcement yet.

Dysfunction Trilogy - Bernanke stole your pension

Collapse
X
 
  • Filter
  • Time
  • Show
Clear All
new posts

  • Dysfunction Trilogy - Bernanke stole your pension

    By Chan Akya This is the second article in a three-part series.
    (Part 1: Keynes stole your ship )

    A core aspect of the logic of folk who support stimulus programs in the name of John Maynard Keynes is that government spending to offset private sector contraction remains a victimless crime. This is completely untrue, and understanding the actual costs of Keynesian machinations by studying real-world examples of dysfunction is important to unravel this pernicious logic.

    In the first part of this series, we considered the impact of random intervention in the shipping sector, in particular the role it has played to crush profits and imperil employment in the sector globally.

    In the second part of this series, we will look at conditions in the area of retirement planning and returns. The notion of stealthy wealth transfers is part of a longer debate that goes into the core aspects of the financial crisis; to a large extent many of the issues have been raised previously in these pages but perhaps more in passing than as the core focus.

    The core function of financial markets is to connect pools of savings with the people who need money for their immediate future. In demographic terms, this can be expressed as markets being the intermediary between older people with savings and young people who need to borrow to set up house, buy cars and other utilitarian requirements.

    Construct of pensions - a quick primer
    This a quick primer, and not all the nuances are or even can be covered in such a short summary. First let's quickly recap the theory here, even if parts of it will appear unrealistic to many readers who have been hardened with real-world experiences over the past few years.

    The rate of return for these old people is meant to take into account two primary factors: the cost of money and the risks entailed. The cost of money is measured by one of two factors - either as the minimum rate of return on money that keeps its purchasing power constant; or as a cumulative measure of opportunity lost by renting it out without risk.

    Typically these two rates are close to the same, or in other words, returns on local government bonds are meant to offset the loss of purchasing power while preserving the principal. Instead of local government bonds, one could consider bank deposits as a suitable alternative.

    Real world impact: if you consider the historical depreciation in the value of money - purchasing power - across the Group of Seven nations, and the needs of a comfortable existence in future, then a realistic return rate on pension portfolios would range between 5% and 10%. Remember also that this rate needs to account for capital withdrawal once people actually retire. Once we remove the periods of overly high inflation as well as stagnation or deflation (that would be you, Japan) the base (minimum) rate works out to 6%. This is the realistic minimum rate that needs to be achieved on pension portfolios, but one could also consider it a weighted average of returns before people actually retire.

    The second aspect, namely risk, is merely a function of (a) the probability of losing principal and (b) the severity of such losses, should they occur. Consider as an example the difference between investing in the share market and investing in a farm. Investments in share markets typically are more volatile, but because of the investment's liquidity the severity of losses is relatively small (that is, people can exit pretty quickly or hedge their losses). In the case of farm investments though, the likelihood of losses is small - because crop yields and animal product prices tend to be fairly similar from year to year; but when there is volatility (for example, because of a natural disaster like a tornado or a hurricane) the extent of losses is usually quite severe.

    Arguably therefore, the compound term risk as an explanatory variable for the above two investments would be quite similar - for stocks a high probability multiplied by a low severity and for farmland a low probability multiplied by a high severity. We could thus say that the expected return of both these investments would be similar.

    (Of course, similar doesn't mean people will be neutral in choosing between the two investments as heuristics would play an important part; a man who saw his brethren suffer significant losses on a farm would be more partial to stock investing, and vice versa).

    This ladder of choices that makes up one's risk preferences contains one more factor of choice, namely the type of returns. While some investors are perfectly happy churning in and out of stocks, selling a part of their portfolio whenever they need to paint the house of example, others would prefer to secure regular returns - that is, coupon payments from the likes of bonds.

    Typically, older people would prefer steady returns as it helps them plan their costs and thus lifestyle, while younger folk could / would withstand greater volatility in their choice of investments as the requirement for immediate income is less (contrast these younger people though with young people - those who don't have net savings, and who need net borrowings to get along).

    Real world impact: To make choices easier for fund managers, various countries around the world have set minimum standards for pension investments in terms of appropriateness, liquidity, maturity or duration matching and so on. Some even prescribe the ideal mix of income generating assets such as bonds and capital growth assets such as stocks.

    The most famous example of such regulations is Employee Retirement Income Security Act in the United States; there are a host of similar initiatives in other countries. Whilst some offer broad guidelines, others get rather specific - for example Dutch pensions aren't allowed direct exposure to physical commodities.

    Performance
    Given the various restrictions on pensions, overall performance in terms of returns has been mediocre to say the least. When you look at 30-year data streams, it is easy to see that mutual funds barely track the performance of broader indices such as the S&P500; this is primarily due to overheads such as management fees and of course, paying for regulatory oversight. For pensions, in addition to the underperformance of mutual funds, one has to add the impact of enforced asset mixes - certain investments in bonds for example as required diversification - and the underperformance becomes even more pronounced.

    This is a core point to consider: asset allocation should not be set in stone, but in the case of pensions the flexibility afforded to managers is perilously low. Consider a situation where the economy is at rock bottom - such as now - and then think of what happens if pension funds are required to continually purchase government bonds even at yields below the rate of inflation (negative real yields). The effect is twofold: firstly to lose money hand over fist for their pensioners and secondly that whenever rates rebound higher, the portfolios also nurse massive mark-to-market losses.

    Real world impact: As some countries require pension managers to exit loss-making assets past a particular threshold, in effect managers end up both buying and selling financial assets at the worst possible times. It is not that these folk are stupid, but rather that their jobs have fairly ill-considered portfolio conditions in place that engender stupidity. And of course, when that kind of scenario prevails, that is, managers simply do not have the ability to apply their skills, the industry gets dumbed down.

    Another factor affecting performance is the construct itself. Underlying assumptions for constructing pension portfolios are driven by actuarial calculations that focus on how long people live and what that means for the mix of income and growth in portfolios.

    If a chap had a life expectancy of 70 and retired at the age of 60, the pension portfolio only needs to be sufficient for 10 years of capital withdrawals. No one wants to save too much and leave a large balance in the pension portfolios for heirs to squabble over, particularly not in countries where estates are taxed on death at punitive rates. So the idea is to match the initial size of the pension pot and target returns with the requirements for capital withdrawals or income generation over a fixed timeframe.

    Real world impact: Typically, pension portfolios assume life expectancies that are lower than those being observed currently. In many countries, pension plans, particularly those from the private sector, state explicitly that payments will be over a fixed term only with a lump sum amount available on maturity - say on a person's 85th birthday.

    The second real world impact, particularly in European countries and now increasingly in the case of the US, is to shift the burden of pension under-payments (due to poor performance for example) and longevity issues to government budgets.

    Indeed, in many countries such as Germany and France, employers pay their pension contributions directly to the government-designated accounts, which then have the responsibility for managing the pension pots. While this spares companies from pension-related risks (remember the famous case of General Motors 10 years ago when the company needed billions of dollars to top up its pensions pot for employees), it also exposes pensioners to worse investment performance as well as residual systemic risk on their sovereign budgets. As a recent real world example, when the Greek government went bust, pensioners in the country suffered the most.

    Analyze the vectors
    So if one chooses to analyze the vectors, we end up looking at the following: mediocre returns, inappropriate asset mixes and incorrect actuarial assumptions. The shift of risk away from private-sector funding to the public sector entails greater urgency in assessing systemic risk of sovereigns, particularly given the mandated asset mix in investment portfolios.

    Real world impact: In the markets, the sum total of all risk calculations is expressed by a single variable, namely price. However, that signal can be easily clouded by government actions. For example, consider what happened when France was downgraded by the rating agencies. Whilst a widening of bond yields against say Germany would have been the correct response, the exact opposite happened because pension plans - thanks to the automatic sell-off requirements that were triggered on French stocks - ended up purchasing more "safe" securities, that is, French government bonds, thereby helping to tighten spreads against better quality sovereigns. Pretty much the same thing happened after the United Kingdom was downgraded a few weeks ago.

    In this dangerous territory of invalid price signals clouding the actual calculations of risk entailed in pension portfolios, we also have had to contend with the actions of central banks, particularly over the past 18 months.

    Uninterrupted purchases of low-risk assets such as government bonds have been pushed through in the name of quantitative easing, intended as it were for investment funds to flow towards more risky assets and eventually, credit creation that could help to regenerate growth.

    But this theory has a fatal flaw that is partly driven by demographics. When a large number of old people expect to receive certain amounts from their pension portfolios, reductions in running yields end up reducing their monthly income. This in turn causes them to cut spending even more as they try to add savings to their overall pot, in effect more than mitigating the positive actions of the central banks.

    There is also the effect of systemic risk in that rising sovereign risk is obvious to pensioners; and as they fear “haircuts� on their pension plans in future, the motivation to save becomes larger. This is also true for people close to pension age (say folks in their 50s) and then slowly extends to those in their 40s and so on. That is precisely what happened in Japan from the mid-'90s to 2012 and now threatens to happen across Europe.

    There is also a pernicious moral perfidy here: going back to the initial definition of financial markets' function, it is obvious that the key intention is to shift money from the hands of savers (generally old people) to those of borrowers (generally younger people).

    In some countries such as the US and the UK, this debate has been framed around race and even immigration. With demographic narrowing in these countries, new entrants are usually the target market for lending by banks; and such folks tend to be immigrants or members of minority communities that have better demographic profiles than the majority.

    Real world impact: It is actually now impossible to construct a pension portfolio with an expected return for 6% whilst meeting investment restrictions set by the authorities. The best that people manage to eke out in general pensions is 2% to 3%; anything higher requires inordinate principal risks. Add in the liability calculation (future payments at the current low discount rates) and effectively every G-7 sovereign is bankrupt many times over when pension deficits are taken into account.

    With all the best intentions, the facts are clear on the ground that Keynesian strategies have been counterproductive, especially for retirees. The larger battle for people's minds though has swung in favor of the Keynesian orthodoxy with the "anything necessary" mantra of European Central Bank president Mario Draghi being taken up with a vengeance by other central bankers from Haruhiko Kuroda in Japan to Ben Bernanke in the US.

    By pushing even more quantitative easing down the throats of their economies, these central bankers are doubling down, but at the cost of pensioners' security in coming decades.

    Have you ever imagined standing in the middle of the road and watching helplessly as a 60-tonne truck barrels down at you at 100 kilometers an hour? That feeling is not dissimilar to what the average retiree now faces.

    http://www.atimes.com/atimes/Global_...01-100513.html

  • #2
    Re: Dysfunction Trilogy - Bernanke stole your pension

    Originally posted by don View Post
    By Chan Akya This is the second article in a three-part series.
    (Part 1: Keynes stole your ship )

    A core aspect of the logic of folk who support stimulus programs in the name of John Maynard Keynes is that government spending to offset private sector contraction remains a victimless crime. This is completely untrue, and understanding the actual costs of Keynesian machinations by studying real-world examples of dysfunction is important to unravel this pernicious logic......

    Real world impact: It is actually now impossible to construct a pension portfolio with an expected return for 6% whilst meeting investment restrictions set by the authorities. The best that people manage to eke out in general pensions is 2% to 3%; anything higher requires inordinate principal risks. Add in the liability calculation (future payments at the current low discount rates) and effectively every G-7 sovereign is bankrupt many times over when pension deficits are taken into account.

    With all the best intentions, the facts are clear on the ground that Keynesian strategies have been counterproductive, especially for retirees. The larger battle for people's minds though has swung in favor of the Keynesian orthodoxy with the "anything necessary" mantra of European Central Bank president Mario Draghi being taken up with a vengeance by other central bankers from Haruhiko Kuroda in Japan to Ben Bernanke in the US.

    By pushing even more quantitative easing down the throats of their economies, these central bankers are doubling down, but at the cost of pensioners' security in coming decades.

    Have you ever imagined standing in the middle of the road and watching helplessly as a 60-tonne truck barrels down at you at 100 kilometers an hour? That feeling is not dissimilar to what the average retiree now faces.

    http://www.atimes.com/atimes/Global_...01-100513.html

    and my trade/biz has felt this directly, as the clientel's investment income/yield has plummeted, so has their spending (in my industry - boating - in particular - and MY customer base is NOT the hedgefund crowd, who's raking it in these daze)

    yet we continue to hear from clowns like krugman, who just today sez there's NO BUBBLE in bonds or stocks?

    Op-Ed Columnist

    Bernanke, Blower of Bubbles?

    By PAUL KRUGMAN

    Published: May 9, 2013

    Bubbles can be bad for your financial health — and bad for the health of the economy, too. The dot-com bubble of the late 1990s left behind many vacant buildings and many more failed dreams. When the housing bubble of the next decade burst, the result was the greatest economic crisis since the 1930s — a crisis from which we have yet to emerge.


    So when people talk about bubbles, you should listen carefully and evaluate their claims — not scornfully dismiss them, which was the way many self-proclaimed experts reacted to warnings about housing.

    And there’s a lot of bubble talk out there right now. Much of it is about an alleged bond bubble that is supposedly keeping bond prices unrealistically high and interest rates — which move in the opposite direction from bond prices — unrealistically low. But the rising Dow has raised fears of a stock bubble, too.

    So do we have a major bond and/or stock bubble? On bonds, I’d say definitely not. On stocks, probably not, although I’m not as certain.

    What is a bubble, anyway? Surprisingly, there’s no standard definition. But I’d define it as a situation in which asset prices appear to be based on implausible or inconsistent views about the future. Dot-com prices in 1999 made sense only if you believed that many companies would all turn out to be a Microsoft; housing prices in 2006 only made sense if you believed that home prices could keep rising much faster than buyers’ incomes for years to come.

    Is there anything comparable going on in today’s bond market? Well, the interest rate on long-term bonds depends mainly on the expected path of short-term interest rates, which are controlled by the Federal Reserve. You don’t want to buy a 10-year bond at less than 2 percent, the current going rate, if you believe that the Fed will be raising short-term rates to 4 percent or 5 percent in the not-too-distant future.

    But why, exactly, should you believe any such thing? The Fed normally cuts rates when unemployment is high and inflation is low — which is the situation today. True, it can’t cut rates any further because they’re already near zero and can’t go lower. (Otherwise investors would just sit on cash.) But it’s hard to see why the Fed should raise rates until unemployment falls a lot and/or inflation surges, and there’s no hint in the data that anything like that is going to happen for years to come.

    (my comment to that would be: starting eating yer i-pad, have we paul???)

    Why, then, all the talk of a bond bubble? Partly it reflects the correct observation that interest rates are very low by historical standards. What you need to bear in mind, however, is that the economy is also in especially terrible shape by historical standards — once-in-three-generations terrible. The usual rules about what constitutes a reasonable level of interest rates don’t apply.

    There’s also, one has to say, an element of wishful thinking here. For whatever reason, many people in the financial industry have developed a deep hatred for Ben Bernanke, the Fed chairman, and everything he does; they want his easy-money policies ended, and they also want to see those policies fail in some spectacular fashion. As it turns out, however, dislike for bearded Princeton professors is not a good basis for investment strategy.

    And one should never forget the example of Japan, where bets against government bonds — justified by more or less the same arguments currently made to justify claims of a U.S. bond bubble — ended in grief so often that the whole trade came to be known as the “widow maker.” At this point, Japan’s debt is well over twice its G.D.P., its budget deficit remains large, and the interest rate on 10-year bonds is 0.6 percent. No, that’s not a misprint.

    O.K., what about stocks? Major stock indexes are now higher than they were at the end of the 1990s, which can sound ominous. It sounds a lot less ominous, however, when you learn that corporate profits — which are, after all, what stocks are shares in — are more than two-and-a-half times higher than they were when the 1990s bubble burst. Also, with bond yields so low, you would expect investors to move into stocks, driving their prices higher.

    All in all, the case for significant bubbles in stocks or, especially, bonds is weak. And that conclusion matters for policy as well as investment.

    For one important subtext of all the recent bubble rhetoric is the demand that Mr. Bernanke and his colleagues stop trying to fight mass unemployment, that they must cease and desist their efforts to boost the economy or dire consequences will follow. In fact, however, there isn’t any case for believing that we face any broad bubble problem, let alone that worrying about hypothetical bubbles should take precedence over the task of getting Americans back to work. Mr. Bernanke should brush aside the babbling barons of bubbleism, and get on with doing his job.
    what phreakin BS!!!

    as IF ZIRP is "creating" any jobs - in the productive economy - whatsoever!
    more propaganda along the lines of "jobs saved or created", right??

    oh sure, residential construction is 'picking up' - to what - less than 1/3 of the peak?
    with car sales are still several million units below the prev high??

    and this political apaRATchik, masquerading as an economist - continues to lay the blame for the economic meltdown - that HIS PARTY politics created - on the conservatives calls for restraint on .gov spending?

    sure - just keep on doubling-down on FREE MONEY to the bankster class - afterall, whats not to like - esp since its good for the dems agenda - and hey!

    for people in HIS age cohort - why worry - they'll all be DEAD by the time the bill for this comes due - so just keep pouring the gasoline on the blazing conflagration that HIS PARTY and their politix/policies have created over the past 40-50 years.

    what could go wrong....
    Last edited by lektrode; May 10, 2013, 10:42 AM.

    Comment


    • #3
      Re: Dysfunction Trilogy - Bernanke stole your pension

      Even Keynes said that you can't prime an economy with just monetary policy. He said it was like "pushing on a string."

      What the Fed is doing isn't Keynesian. Were he alive, I'm sure he wouldn't want his name attached to this stuff.

      Comment


      • #4
        Re: Dysfunction Trilogy - Bernanke stole your pension

        Originally posted by dcarrigg View Post
        Even Keynes said that you can't prime an economy with just monetary policy. He said it was like "pushing on a string."

        What the Fed is doing isn't Keynesian. Were he alive, I'm sure he wouldn't want his name attached to this stuff.
        This is a good point. I frequently rant about Keynesianism, but it is more correct to talk about the modern interpretation of it in Anglo-Saxon economies, replete with graft.

        Thanks for the reminder!

        Comment


        • #5
          Re: Dysfunction Trilogy - Bernanke stole your pension

          Originally posted by astonas View Post
          This is a good point. I frequently rant about Keynesianism, but it is more correct to talk about the modern interpretation of it in Anglo-Saxon economies, replete with graft.

          Thanks for the reminder!
          If there's a different interpretation of it in the "non-Anglo" G7 countries it sure isn't apparent to me :-)

          Comment


          • #6
            Re: Dysfunction Trilogy - Bernanke stole your pension

            Originally posted by GRG55 View Post
            If there's a different interpretation of it in the "non-Anglo" G7 countries it sure isn't apparent to me :-)
            Indeed. The worldwide prescription for this long recession (or slow recovery, whatever you want to call it) seems to be to keep at least modestly austere fiscal policy whilst having a loose, footloose and fancy-free monetary policy.

            To be honest, I don't even think there's a word for that combination.

            Comment


            • #7
              Re: Dysfunction Trilogy - Bernanke stole your pension

              Originally posted by dcarrigg View Post
              Indeed. The worldwide prescription for this long recession (or slow recovery, whatever you want to call it) seems to be to keep at least modestly austere fiscal policy whilst having a loose, footloose and fancy-free monetary policy.

              To be honest, I don't even think there's a word for that combination.
              I'm not convinced the austere fiscal policies are all that austere...public debt loads just keep rising and rising everywhere. We are now conditioned to believe that a reduction in a fiscal deficit is a hardship imposed by a heartless government bent on subjugating workers by "the left", or that a slowing of the rate of public debt accumulation is some sort of magnificent achievement on the part of our political leaders by "the right".

              At the same time so many economies all around the world, China among them, have become so dependent on the public sector finance/subsidy or the public sector demand component that they cannot grow without it and therefore it is impossible to withdraw any part of it.

              This game may go on for some time yet, but at some point there just has to be public sector debt defaults or debt forgiveness...and that apparent capital destruction might be what puts us into an extended global recession/depression in due course?

              I just cannot see how it is possible to simply inflate away a debt that keeps growing...
              Last edited by GRG55; May 10, 2013, 11:57 PM.

              Comment


              • #8
                Re: Dysfunction Trilogy - Bernanke stole your pension

                there is no keynesian policy in the real world, and there never will be. first, as has been pointed out by dcarrigg, keynes focused more on fiscal stimulus than monetary, and in spite of the large deficits being run, the fiscal stimulus is still inadequate to e.g. provide employment opportunities for millions who've given up even looking for work. further, although keynes prescribed deficit spending as fiscal stimulus during downturns, i don't believe he would have condoned enormous deficit spending even during boom times. and politicians in the real world can't resist that particular cookie jar.

                Comment

                Working...
                X