With most of the issues grappled with here at our particular moment I have this sinking feeling that I'm like a ham-fisted detective, too dense to read the clues and end up just muddying the "crime scene" and ending up both despondent and panicked: the "culprit(s)" always just elude me.
- is it fiat?
- is it debt?
- is it fraud?
- is it FIRE?
- is it central banking as a notion or the Fed in particular?
- is it debt per-se that's the problem or is it the symptom of a system that simply must have nominal growth and therefore, puppet like, some sector will run headlong into debt
- is it the logic of dollar hegemony slowly working its magic with financialisation to produce a kind of monster child that no-one can deny is beautiful because they all had a hand in creating the love child?
- is it crony capitalism that could become un-crony capitalism or is crony capitalism the best outcome we could have given globalisation (hey, at least some westerners are benefitting?)
- is finacialisation serving globalisation or is it the other way around?
- is Keynsian stimulous (still) the only way to get out of a debt bubble (insufficient aggregate demand) when you have a negative return on stimulous in terms of demand as appears to be the case? (That really seems a new blind alley.)
And on and on...
I suspect that we could all come up with a similar list of fundamental questions that somehow seem just as opaque now as they did say 5 years ago (or at least I flatter myself that everyone's as confused as I am.)
Hell, after reading Mosler's piece that I referenced here I couldn't even articulate what "fiscal responsibility" in government would mean?
(I am not a good student in my middle age.)
For what it's worth, I thought the following essay actually struck at the root of some of this. Or at least voiced the suspicion that there's something behind the bug-bears that I certainly fixate on (financial fraud for example) that might actually be more fundamental and challenging than the bug-bear itself.
http://www.nakedcapitalism.com/2012/...al-issues.html
Just to avoid confusion, here are the passages that struck home for me:
After a quick review of the great depression he comments:
Polish economist Michal Kalecki as the Dimitri Orlov of the (post) depression era?:
The great Polish economist Michal Kalecki noticed this dynamic early on and rightly predicted that it would have enormous consequences for any mixed economy. In his classic paper The Political
Well, that's not very selective is it? But I actually think that Pilkington is doing some hard work here and - ultimately - it's worth reading the whole thing.
The point to me is that I think he's put some menace into the time-worn comparison's to the great depression and highlighted how potentially fractious these issues are. [And intractable: it is sooo familiar nooo?]
Just to give some emotion to what I'm saying, I recall watching as a kid some BBC documentary about the general strike in Britain in the 20s. I remember being really disturbed by the idea that young men from wealthy families felt compelled (in whatever number) to oppose the strike and take to the streets in apparent defense of public services. Frankly what struck me as both incomprehensible and frightening while I watched it - roughly early eighties I would guess - was the idea that some politics could actually penetrate so close to my age group and in such a recognizable city context (my extended family was in London and we went there every other year roughly.) The conflict was unresolved for me: which tribe would we have belonged to? Was it the right one?
- is it fiat?
- is it debt?
- is it fraud?
- is it FIRE?
- is it central banking as a notion or the Fed in particular?
- is it debt per-se that's the problem or is it the symptom of a system that simply must have nominal growth and therefore, puppet like, some sector will run headlong into debt
- is it the logic of dollar hegemony slowly working its magic with financialisation to produce a kind of monster child that no-one can deny is beautiful because they all had a hand in creating the love child?
- is it crony capitalism that could become un-crony capitalism or is crony capitalism the best outcome we could have given globalisation (hey, at least some westerners are benefitting?)
- is finacialisation serving globalisation or is it the other way around?
- is Keynsian stimulous (still) the only way to get out of a debt bubble (insufficient aggregate demand) when you have a negative return on stimulous in terms of demand as appears to be the case? (That really seems a new blind alley.)
And on and on...
I suspect that we could all come up with a similar list of fundamental questions that somehow seem just as opaque now as they did say 5 years ago (or at least I flatter myself that everyone's as confused as I am.)
Hell, after reading Mosler's piece that I referenced here I couldn't even articulate what "fiscal responsibility" in government would mean?
(I am not a good student in my middle age.)
For what it's worth, I thought the following essay actually struck at the root of some of this. Or at least voiced the suspicion that there's something behind the bug-bears that I certainly fixate on (financial fraud for example) that might actually be more fundamental and challenging than the bug-bear itself.
http://www.nakedcapitalism.com/2012/...al-issues.html
Just to avoid confusion, here are the passages that struck home for me:
After a quick review of the great depression he comments:
What lessons should be taken from this? Quite simple ones. Democratic capitalism is a deeply dysfunctional, perhaps even suicidal system. In the good times capitalists and financiers gain ever more power to influence politicians and, after a brief retreat when crisis occurs, they continue to hold this influence when the deflationary pressures set in. Meanwhile, the policymakers convince themselves that the government budget is the same as a household budget – and in this are supported by numerous economists. This leads to a sort of ‘perfect storm’ situation where the budget deficit becomes the main issue of the day and all else is ignored, including the declining economy.
The business class, together with those elected officials who have become their representatives, feel threatened by any added government intervention. They see in it an attack on their own power. That may seem paradoxical in the case of government officials. Surely, after all, they would see their power increase with increased government intervention. In theory, yes; in practice, no. These officials are so enmeshed in the web of business and moneymaking that any increase in government intervention would appear to them threatening. This is not dissimilar to a journalist embedded with troops in a warzone. Because they become so dependent on the troops for their livelihood they tend to lose all distance from what is going on around them and become one of the gang, as it were. Ditto for the politicians.
The business class, together with those elected officials who have become their representatives, feel threatened by any added government intervention. They see in it an attack on their own power. That may seem paradoxical in the case of government officials. Surely, after all, they would see their power increase with increased government intervention. In theory, yes; in practice, no. These officials are so enmeshed in the web of business and moneymaking that any increase in government intervention would appear to them threatening. This is not dissimilar to a journalist embedded with troops in a warzone. Because they become so dependent on the troops for their livelihood they tend to lose all distance from what is going on around them and become one of the gang, as it were. Ditto for the politicians.
The great Polish economist Michal Kalecki noticed this dynamic early on and rightly predicted that it would have enormous consequences for any mixed economy. In his classic paper The Political
Consequences of Full Employment
he wrote:
First he notes how this aversion manifests itself – today’s reader will be impressed to know that Kalecki was writing in 1943.
There are, however, even more direct indications that a first-class political issue is at stake here. In the great depression in the 1930s, big business consistently opposed experiments for increasing employment by government spending in all countries, except Nazi Germany. This was to be clearly seen in the USA (opposition to the New Deal), in France (the Blum experiment), and in Germany before Hitler. The attitude is not easy to explain. Clearly, higher output and employment benefit not only workers but entrepreneurs as well, because the latter’s profits rise. And the policy of full employment outlined above does not encroach upon profits because it does not involve any additional taxation. The entrepreneurs in the slump are longing for a boom; why do they not gladly accept the synthetic boom which the government is able to offer them? It is this difficult and fascinating question.
Kalecki rightly noted that deficit-financed spending was in the interest of the business class. Especially in a depression, when output and hence profits were so low, it is only the government that can return capitalism to prosperity – and yet, capitalists are remarkably hostile to such action, preferring to wallow in a stagnant economy rather than accept assistance. From an economic perspective – which assumes that businessmen care about profits above all else – this makes little sense. But to Kalecki’s mind it was perfectly logical.First he notes how this aversion manifests itself – today’s reader will be impressed to know that Kalecki was writing in 1943.
Every widening of state activity is looked upon by business with suspicion, but the creation of employment by government spending has a special aspect which makes the opposition particularly intense. Under a laissez-faire system the level of employment depends to a great extent on the so-called state of confidence. If this deteriorates, private investment declines, which results in a fall of output and employment (both directly and through the secondary effect of the fall in incomes upon consumption and investment). This gives the capitalists a powerful indirect control over government policy: everything which may shake the state of confidence must be carefully avoided because it would cause an economic crisis. But once the government learns the trick of increasing employment by its own purchases, this powerful controlling device loses its effectiveness. Hence budget deficits necessary to carry out government intervention must be regarded as perilous. The social function of the doctrine of ‘sound finance’ is to make the level of employment dependent on the state of confidence.
Kalecki moves from this highly illogical position to more reasonable ideas that might circulate around the business class:The dislike of business leaders for a government spending policy grows even more acute when they come to consider the objects on which the money would be spent: public investment and subsidizing mass consumption.
The economic principles of government intervention require that public investment should be confined to objects which do not compete with the equipment of private business (e.g. hospitals, schools, highways). Otherwise the profitability of private investment might be impaired, and the positive effect of public investment upon employment offset, by the negative effect of the decline in private investment.
And so Kalecki suggests that the business class may then favour directly subsidised consumption. But this proves not to be the case.The economic principles of government intervention require that public investment should be confined to objects which do not compete with the equipment of private business (e.g. hospitals, schools, highways). Otherwise the profitability of private investment might be impaired, and the positive effect of public investment upon employment offset, by the negative effect of the decline in private investment.
[S]ubsidizing mass consumption is much more violently opposed by these experts than public investment. For here a moral principle of the highest importance is at stake. The fundamentals of capitalist ethics require that ‘you shall earn your bread in sweat’ – unless you happen to have private means.
So much nonsense. But what lies behind it is anything but. Because Kalecki then goes on to argue that such intervention makes the business class wary that its power might be eroded. For one, a regime in which the government could hire people to alleviate unemployment threatens the businessman’s main disciplinary measure: the sack. This could well lead to an erosion of his social power.
The point to me is that I think he's put some menace into the time-worn comparison's to the great depression and highlighted how potentially fractious these issues are. [And intractable: it is sooo familiar nooo?]
Just to give some emotion to what I'm saying, I recall watching as a kid some BBC documentary about the general strike in Britain in the 20s. I remember being really disturbed by the idea that young men from wealthy families felt compelled (in whatever number) to oppose the strike and take to the streets in apparent defense of public services. Frankly what struck me as both incomprehensible and frightening while I watched it - roughly early eighties I would guess - was the idea that some politics could actually penetrate so close to my age group and in such a recognizable city context (my extended family was in London and we went there every other year roughly.) The conflict was unresolved for me: which tribe would we have belonged to? Was it the right one?
Comment