Really interesting discussion with the author of American Colossus: The Triumph of Capitalism by H. W. Brands (see second item, October 22):
http://www.bloomberg.com/podcasts/lapham/
History is another country... we keep returning to again and again.
I've been musing over my level of crankiness of late and so went on the search of a critical review. Here's one that makes an interesting point:
"For all the pleasure that "Colossus" offers in the way of anecdote, two flaws undermine its attractions. First, Mr. Brands frames the book—and indeed all of American history—as a contest between capitalism and democracy. Democracy depends on equality, the author claims, while capitalism needs inequality to function. "In accomplishing its revolution, capitalism threatened to eclipse American democracy," he writes.
The author's attachment to a sweeping theme like the democracy-capitalism clash is understandable: It's the sort of duel that Will and Ariel Durant and other producers of pageant-style history have featured to unify their multivolume works.
Still, this "wasn't it grand?" mode of writing is imprecise. Mr. Brands laments that capitalism's triumph in the late 19th century created a disparity between the "wealthy class" and the common man that dwarfs any difference of income in our modern distribution tables. But this pitting of capitalism against democracy will not hold. When the word "class" crops up in economic discussions, watch out: it implies a perception of society held in thrall to a static economy of rigid social tiers. Capitalism might indeed preclude democracy if capitalism meant that rich people really were a permanent class, always able to keep the money they amass and collect an ever greater share. But Americans are an unruly bunch and do not stay in their classes. The lesson of the late 19th century is that genuine capitalism is a force of creative destruction, just as Joseph Schumpeter later recognized. Snapshots of rich versus poor cannot capture the more important dynamic, which occurs over time.
One capitalist idea (the railroad, say) brutally supplants another (the shipping canal). Within a few generations—and in thoroughly democratic fashion—this supplanting knocks some families out of the top tier and elevates others to it. Some poor families vault to the middle class, others drop out. If Mr. Brands were right, and the "triumph of capitalism" had deadened democracy and created a permanent overclass, Forbes's 2010 list of billionaires would today be populated by Rockefellers, Morgans and Carnegies. The main legacy of titans, former or current, is that the innovations they support will produce social benefits, from the steel-making to the Internet.
The second failing of "Colossus" is its perpetuation of the robber-baron myth. Years ago, historian Burton Folsom noted the difference between what he labeled political entrepreneurs and market entrepreneurs. The political entrepreneur tends to compete over finite assets—or even to steal them—and therefore deserves the "robber baron" moniker. An example that Mr. Folsom provided: the ferry magnate Robert Fulton, who operated successfully on the Hudson thanks to a 30-year exclusive concession from the New York state legislature. Russia's petrocrats nowadays enjoy similar protections. Neither Fulton nor the petrocrats qualify as true capitalists.
Market entrepreneurs, by contrast, vanquish the competition by overtaking it. On some days Cornelius Vanderbilt was a political entrepreneur—perhaps when he ruined those traitorous partners, for instance. But most days Vanderbilt typified the market entrepreneur, ruining Fulton's monopoly in the 1820s with lower fares, the innovative and cost-saving tubular boiler and a splendid advertising logo: "New Jersey Must Be Free." With market entrepreneurship, a third party also wins: the consumer. Market entrepreneurs are not true robbers, for their ruining serves the common good.
Mr. Brands appreciates the distinction between political entrepreneurs and market entrepreneurs, but he chooses not to highlight it. Thus he misses an opportunity to emphasize a truth about the late 19th century that rings down to our own rocky times: The best growth is spurred by the right kind of ruin."
Source: http://online.wsj.com/article/SB1000...139071998.html
Not a bad test of the FIRE economy thesis: is there really a difference in kind between the real economy and the FIRE economy, or is it a phantom difference, like that between Vanderbilt 1 and 2 above, and the only relevant reality is success or failure?
http://www.bloomberg.com/podcasts/lapham/
History is another country... we keep returning to again and again.
I've been musing over my level of crankiness of late and so went on the search of a critical review. Here's one that makes an interesting point:
"For all the pleasure that "Colossus" offers in the way of anecdote, two flaws undermine its attractions. First, Mr. Brands frames the book—and indeed all of American history—as a contest between capitalism and democracy. Democracy depends on equality, the author claims, while capitalism needs inequality to function. "In accomplishing its revolution, capitalism threatened to eclipse American democracy," he writes.
The author's attachment to a sweeping theme like the democracy-capitalism clash is understandable: It's the sort of duel that Will and Ariel Durant and other producers of pageant-style history have featured to unify their multivolume works.
Still, this "wasn't it grand?" mode of writing is imprecise. Mr. Brands laments that capitalism's triumph in the late 19th century created a disparity between the "wealthy class" and the common man that dwarfs any difference of income in our modern distribution tables. But this pitting of capitalism against democracy will not hold. When the word "class" crops up in economic discussions, watch out: it implies a perception of society held in thrall to a static economy of rigid social tiers. Capitalism might indeed preclude democracy if capitalism meant that rich people really were a permanent class, always able to keep the money they amass and collect an ever greater share. But Americans are an unruly bunch and do not stay in their classes. The lesson of the late 19th century is that genuine capitalism is a force of creative destruction, just as Joseph Schumpeter later recognized. Snapshots of rich versus poor cannot capture the more important dynamic, which occurs over time.
One capitalist idea (the railroad, say) brutally supplants another (the shipping canal). Within a few generations—and in thoroughly democratic fashion—this supplanting knocks some families out of the top tier and elevates others to it. Some poor families vault to the middle class, others drop out. If Mr. Brands were right, and the "triumph of capitalism" had deadened democracy and created a permanent overclass, Forbes's 2010 list of billionaires would today be populated by Rockefellers, Morgans and Carnegies. The main legacy of titans, former or current, is that the innovations they support will produce social benefits, from the steel-making to the Internet.
The second failing of "Colossus" is its perpetuation of the robber-baron myth. Years ago, historian Burton Folsom noted the difference between what he labeled political entrepreneurs and market entrepreneurs. The political entrepreneur tends to compete over finite assets—or even to steal them—and therefore deserves the "robber baron" moniker. An example that Mr. Folsom provided: the ferry magnate Robert Fulton, who operated successfully on the Hudson thanks to a 30-year exclusive concession from the New York state legislature. Russia's petrocrats nowadays enjoy similar protections. Neither Fulton nor the petrocrats qualify as true capitalists.
Market entrepreneurs, by contrast, vanquish the competition by overtaking it. On some days Cornelius Vanderbilt was a political entrepreneur—perhaps when he ruined those traitorous partners, for instance. But most days Vanderbilt typified the market entrepreneur, ruining Fulton's monopoly in the 1820s with lower fares, the innovative and cost-saving tubular boiler and a splendid advertising logo: "New Jersey Must Be Free." With market entrepreneurship, a third party also wins: the consumer. Market entrepreneurs are not true robbers, for their ruining serves the common good.
Mr. Brands appreciates the distinction between political entrepreneurs and market entrepreneurs, but he chooses not to highlight it. Thus he misses an opportunity to emphasize a truth about the late 19th century that rings down to our own rocky times: The best growth is spurred by the right kind of ruin."
Source: http://online.wsj.com/article/SB1000...139071998.html
Not a bad test of the FIRE economy thesis: is there really a difference in kind between the real economy and the FIRE economy, or is it a phantom difference, like that between Vanderbilt 1 and 2 above, and the only relevant reality is success or failure?
Comment