Announcement

Collapse
No announcement yet.

Treasurys Up Sharply on Housing Market Concerns

Collapse
X
 
  • Filter
  • Time
  • Show
Clear All
new posts

  • Treasurys Up Sharply on Housing Market Concerns

    http://biz.yahoo.com/ap/070710/bonds.html?.v=4

    AP
    Treasurys Up Sharply on Housing Concerns
    Tuesday July 10, 11:26 am ET
    Treasurys Up Sharply on Housing Market Concerns


    NEW YORK (AP) -- U.S. Treasury bond prices rose sharply on Tuesday as renewed fears about the health of the housing market and speculation about stronger demand for the securities from pension funds tipped off a buying spree.

    At 11 a.m. EDT, the 10-year Treasury note was up $5.63 per $1,000 in face value, or 18/32 point, from its level at 5 p.m. Monday. Its yield, which moves in the opposite direction, fell to 5.07 percent from 5.15 percent.

    The 30-year bond rose 1 4/32 point. Its yield fell to 5.16 percent from 5.24 percent.

    The 2-year note rose 4/32 point. Its yield fell to 4.90 percent from 4.95 percent.

    Yields on 3-month Treasury bills were 4.96 percent as the discount rate rose 0.02 percentage point to 4.82 percent.

    Bond prices and yields move inversely.

    Part of the buying impetus came from dire reports from homebuilder D.R. Horton and Home Depot.

    D.R. Horton, the nation's largest homebuilder, warned of a third-quarter loss due to a 40 percent dive in orders for new homes.

    The announcement coincided with Home Depot lowering its earnings projection for this year by 15 percent, citing weaker conditions in the housing market.

    Investors, fearing this could mark a watershed in the deterioration of the U.S. housing market, bought into government paper.

    Like Fred previously posted, once you understand the game all seems anticlimactic when it unfolds...Yawn.

  • #2
    Re: Treasurys Up Sharply on Housing Market Concerns

    Originally posted by Sapiens View Post
    http://biz.yahoo.com/ap/070710/bonds.html?.v=4


    Like Fred previously posted, once you understand the game all seems anticlimactic when it unfolds...Yawn.
    Bernie is going to be explaining the gameplan to everyone in another 10 minutes.
    "Men, it has been well said, think in herds; it will be seen that they go mad in herds, while they only recover their senses slowly, and one by one."
    - Charles Mackay

    Comment


    • #3
      Re: Treasurys Up Sharply on Housing Market Concerns

      Originally posted by Tet View Post
      Bernie is going to be explaining the gameplan to everyone in another 10 minutes.

      http://www.federalreserve.gov/boardd...10/default.htm

      Remarks by Chairman Ben S. Bernanke
      At the Monetary Economics Workshop of the National Bureau of Economic Research Summer Institute, Cambridge, Massachusetts
      July 10, 2007
      Inflation Expectations and Inflation Forecasting

      I would like to thank Christina Romer and David Romer for giving me the chance to address participants in the Summer Institute, sponsored by the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER). As an academic, I regularly attended the Summer Institute and presented or commented on research here. I also served for a time as the director of the Monetary Economics group, the position now shared by David and Christina. The informal nature of the institute, the large number of talented people in attendance, and the opportunity to hear about the very latest work in the field--often while in early draft form--made these few weeks each summer one of the most stimulating times of the year for me. In my current position, I am keenly aware of the long history of fruitful interaction between economists inside and outside of central banks, and I am eager to see this interaction continue. This ongoing intellectual exchange, by improving our understanding of the economy and the workings of monetary policy, has had and will continue to have sizable benefits.

      Today I will offer a few remarks on the relationships among monetary policy, inflation, and the public's expectations of inflation, focusing--as seems appropriate for this audience--on some important open questions. I will also give a short overview of the way the Federal Reserve Board staff forecasts inflation, including some discussion of how the staff incorporates information about expected inflation into its forecasting process.

      As you know, the control of inflation is central to good monetary policy. Price stability, which is one leg of the Federal Reserve's dual mandate from the Congress, is a good thing in itself, for reasons that economists understand much better today than they did a few decades ago. Inflation injects noise into the price system, makes long-term financial planning more complex, and interacts in perverse ways with imperfectly indexed tax and accounting rules. In the short-to-medium term, the maintenance of price stability helps avoid the pattern of stop-go monetary policies that were the source of much instability in output and employment in the past. More fundamentally, experience suggests that high and persistent inflation undermines public confidence in the economy and in the management of economic policy generally, with potentially adverse effects on risk-taking, investment, and other productive activities that are sensitive to the public's assessments of the prospects for future economic stability. In the long term, low inflation promotes growth, efficiency, and stability--which, all else being equal, support maximum sustainable employment, the other leg of the mandate given to the Federal Reserve by the Congress.

      Admittedly, measuring the long-term relationship between growth or productivity and inflation is difficult. For example, it may be that low inflation has accompanied good economic performance in part because countries that maintain low inflation tend to pursue other sound economic policies as well. Still, I think we can agree that, at a minimum, the opposite proposition--that inflationary policies promote employment growth in the long run--has been entirely discredited and, indeed, that policies based on this proposition have led to very bad outcomes whenever they have been applied.

      Inflation Expectations: Conceptual Frameworks
      Undoubtedly, the state of inflation expectations greatly influences actual inflation and thus the central bank's ability to achieve price stability. But what do we mean, precisely, by "the state of inflation expectations"? How should we measure inflation expectations, and how should we use that information for forecasting and controlling inflation? I certainly do not have complete answers to those questions, but I believe that they are of great practical importance. I hope my remarks here will stimulate some of you to work on these issues.

      What is the right conceptual framework for thinking about inflation expectations in the current context? The traditional rational-expectations model of inflation and inflation expectations has been a useful workhorse for thinking about issues of credibility and institutional design, but, to my mind, it is less helpful for thinking about economies in which (1) the structure of the economy is constantly evolving in ways that are imperfectly understood by both the public and policymakers and (2) the policymakers' objective function is not fully known by private agents. In particular, together with the assumption that the central bank's objective function is fixed and known to the public, the traditional rational-expectations approach implies that the public has firm knowledge of the long-run equilibrium inflation rate; consequently, their long-run inflation expectations do not vary over time in response to new information.

      But in fact, as I will discuss in more detail later, long-run inflation expectations do vary over time. That is, they are not perfectly anchored in real economies; moreover, the extent to which they are anchored can change, depending on economic developments and (most important) the current and past conduct of monetary policy. In this context, I use the term "anchored" to mean relatively insensitive to incoming data. So, for example, if the public experiences a spell of inflation higher than their long-run expectation, but their long-run expectation of inflation changes little as a result, then inflation expectations are well anchored. If, on the other hand, the public reacts to a short period of higher-than-expected inflation by marking up their long-run expectation considerably, then expectations are poorly anchored.

      Although variations in the extent to which inflation expectations are anchored are not easily handled in a traditional rational-expectations framework, they seem to fit quite naturally into the burgeoning literature on learning in macroeconomics. The premise of this literature is that people do not have full information about the economy or about the objectives of the central bank, but they instead must make statistical inferences about the unknown parameters governing the evolution of the economy. In a learning context, the concept of anchored expectations is easily formalized in a variety of ways; in general, if the public is modeled as being confident in its current estimate of the long-run inflation rate, so that new information has relatively little effect on that estimate, then the essential idea of well-anchored expectations has been captured.

      Allowing for learning has important implications for how we think about the economy and policy. For example, some work has shown that the process of learning can affect the dynamics and even the potential stability of the economy (see, of many possible examples, Bullard and Mitra, 2002). Considerations of how the public learns about the economy affect the form of optimal monetary policy (Gaspar, Smets, and Vestin, 2006). Notably, in a world with rational expectations and in which private agents are assumed already to understand all aspects of the economic environment, talking about the effects of central bank communication would not be sensible, whereas models with learning accommodate the analysis of communication-related issues quite well (Orphanides and Williams, 2005; Bernanke, 2004). Macroeconomic models with learning also give content to the idea of an economy moving gradually from one regime to another, particularly if the central bank as well as the public is assumed to be updating its beliefs. For example, if the central bank and the public learn from experience that high inflation imposes greater costs and fewer benefits than previously thought, then the equilibrium will adjust toward one with lower inflation and lower inflation expectations. This line of explanation of how economies move between monetary regimes, which has been explored by Sargent and others, strikes me as quite plausible as a historical description (Sargent, 1999). In sum, many of the most interesting issues in contemporary monetary theory require an analytical framework that involves learning by private agents and possibly the central bank as well.

      Implications of Anchored Inflation Expectations
      Why do we care about the variability of inflation expectations? As my colleague Rick Mishkin recently discussed, the extent to which inflation expectations are anchored has first-order implications for the performance of inflation and of the economy more generally (Mishkin, 2007). Mishkin illustrated this point by considering the implications of the fact that inflation expectations have become much better anchored over the past thirty years for the estimated coefficients of the conventional Phillips curve, which I define here to encompass specifications that use lagged values of inflation to proxy for expectations or other sources of inflation inertia. As he noted, many studies of the conventional Phillips curve find that the sensitivity of inflation to activity indicators is lower today than in the past (that is, the Phillips curve appears to have become flatter);1 and that the long-run effect on inflation of "supply shocks," such as changes in the price of oil, also appears to be lower than in the past (Hooker, 2002). These findings are of much more than academic interest. To the extent that the Phillips curve may have flattened, inflation will now tend to be more stable than in the past in the face of variations in aggregate demand. (Of course, this can be a good thing or a bad thing, depending on whether inflation expectations are anchored in the vicinity of price stability.) Likewise, a lower sensitivity of long-run inflation to supply shocks would imply that such shocks are much less likely to generate economic instability today than they would have been several decades ago. Notably, the sharp increases in energy prices over the past few years have not led either to persistent inflation or to a recession, in contrast (for example) to the U.S. experience of the 1970s.

      Various factors might account for these changes in the Phillips curve, but, as Mishkin pointed out, better-anchored inflation expectations--themselves, of course, the product of monetary policies that brought inflation down and have kept it relatively stable--certainly play some role. If people set prices and wages with reference to the rate of inflation they expect in the long run and if inflation expectations respond less than previously to variations in economic activity, then inflation itself will become relatively more insensitive to the level of activity--that is, the conventional Phillips curve will be flatter.

      Similar logic explains the finding that inflation is less responsive than it used to be to changes in oil prices and other supply shocks. Certainly, increases in energy prices affect overall inflation in the short run because energy products such as gasoline are part of the consumer's basket and because energy costs loom large in the production of some goods and services. However, a one-off change in energy prices can translate into persistent inflation only if it leads to higher expected inflation and a consequent "wage-price spiral." With inflation expectations well anchored, a one-time increase in energy prices should not lead to a permanent increase in inflation but only to a change in relative prices. A related implication is that, if inflation expectations are well anchored, changes in energy (and food) prices should have relatively little influence on "core" inflation, that is, inflation excluding the prices of food and energy.

      Although inflation expectations seem much better anchored today than they were a few decades ago, they appear to remain imperfectly anchored. A number of studies confirm that observation. For example, Gürkaynak, Sack, and Swanson (2005) found that long-run inflation expectations, as measured by the difference in yields between nominal and inflation-indexed bonds, move in response to news about the economy, rather than remaining unaffected. Levin, Natalucci, and Piger (2004) have shown that some survey measures of inflation expectations in the United States respond to recent changes in the actual rate of inflation, which would not be the case if expectations were perfectly anchored. Models of the term structure of interest rates better fit the data under the assumption that both inflation expectations and beliefs about the central bank's reaction function are evolving (Kozicki and Tinsley, 2001; Rudebusch and Wu, 2003; Cogley, 2005).

      An indirect but elegant way to make the point that inflation expectations remain imperfectly anchored comes from a statistical analysis of inflation by Stock and Watson (2007). Stock and Watson model inflation as having two components, which may be interpreted as the trend and the cycle. Changes in the trend component are highly persistent whereas shocks to the cyclical component are temporary.2 The key finding of this research is that the variability of the trend component of inflation (and thus the share of the overall variability of inflation that it can explain) appears to have fallen significantly after about 1983. That is, unexpected changes in inflation are today much more likely to be transitory than they were before the early 1980s. Because it seems quite unlikely that changes in inflation could persist indefinitely unless long-run expectations of inflation also changed, I interpret the Stock-Watson finding as consistent with the view that inflation expectations have become much more anchored since the early 1980s. At the same time, that the variability of the trend component of inflation, though modest, remains positive, implies that long-run expectations of inflation are not perfectly anchored today.

      The policy implications of the much-improved but still imperfect anchoring of inflation expectations are not at all straightforward. To evaluate these implications, we must understand better the historical variation in inflation expectations, the effect of this variation on actual inflation and economic activity, and the relationship between policy actions and the formation of inflation expectations. With the hope of promoting progress on these broad topics, I pose three questions to researchers, the answer to any of which would be quite useful for practical policymaking.

      First, how should the central bank best monitor the public's inflation expectations? Theoretical treatments tend to neglect the fact that in practice many measures of inflation expectations exist, including the forecasts of professional economists, results from surveys of consumers, information extracted from financial markets such as the market for inflation-indexed debt, and limited information on firms' pricing plans. In a very interesting paper, Mankiw, Reis, and Wolfers (2003) compared the available measures, emphasizing in particular that median measures of inflation expectations often obscure substantial cross-sectional dispersion of expectations.3 On which measure or combination of measures should central bankers focus to assess inflation developments and the degree to which expectations are anchored? Do we need new measures of expectations or new surveys? Information on the price expectations of businesses--who are, after all, the price setters in the first instance--as well as information on nominal wage expectations is particularly scarce.

      Second, how do changes in various measures of inflation expectations feed through to actual pricing behavior? Promising recent research has looked at price changes at very disaggregated levels for insight into the pricing decision (Bils and Klenow, 2004; Nakamura and Steinsson, 2007). But this research has not yet linked pricing decisions at the microeconomic level to inflation expectations; undertaking that next step would no doubt be difficult but also very valuable.
      Third, what factors affect the level of inflation expectations and the degree to which they are anchored? Answering this question essentially involves estimating the learning rule followed by the public or various components of the public, although one could consider alternative frameworks like Carroll's (2003) epidemiological model of the propagation of information among private agents. A fuller understanding of the public's learning rules would improve the central bank's capacity to assess its own credibility, to evaluate the implications of its policy decisions and communications strategy, and perhaps to forecast inflation. Realistically calibrated models with learning would also inform our thinking about policy and the economy.

      Inflation Forecasting at the Federal Reserve
      I would like to shift gears at this point to tell you a bit about how the Federal Reserve Board staff goes about forecasting inflation. Obviously, this activity provides critical inputs into the making of monetary policy, and as I will discuss, the staff's long-term track record in forecasting inflation is quite good by any reasonable benchmark. I hope that my brief description will stimulate your interest in the complex and challenging problems of real-time macroeconomic forecasting. But, as you will see, the discussion of practical inflation forecasting will bring us back to one theme of my remarks--that our ability to forecast inflation and predict how inflation will respond to policy actions depends very much on our capacity to measure and to understand what determines the public's expectations of inflation.

      The Board staff employs a variety of formal models, both structural and purely statistical, in its forecasting efforts. However, the forecasts of inflation (and of other key macroeconomic variables) that are provided to the Federal Open Market Committee are developed through an eclectic process that combines model-based projections, anecdotal and other "extra-model" information, and professional judgment. In short, for all the advances that have been made in modeling and statistical analysis, practical forecasting continues to involve art as well as science.

      The forecasting procedures used depend importantly on the forecast horizon. For near-term inflation forecasting--say, for the current quarter and the next--the staff relies most heavily on a disaggregated, bottom-up approach that focuses on estimating and forecasting price behavior for the various categories of goods and services that make up the aggregate price index in question. For example, we know from historical experience that the prices of some types of goods and services tend to be quite volatile, including not only (as is well known) the prices of energy and some types of food but also some "core" prices such as airfares, apparel prices, and hotel rates. The monthly autocorrelations of price changes in these categories tend to be low or even negative. In contrast, changes in inflation rates in some services categories, such as shelter costs, tend to be more persistent. In assessing what price changes in a particular category imply for future price changes in that category, the staff uses not only various forms of time-series analysis but also specialized knowledge about how the various indexes are constructed--for example, whether certain categories are sampled every month in all localities and how seasonal adjustments are performed. In making very near-term price forecasts, the staff also uses diverse information from a variety of sources, such as surveys of prices of gasoline and other important items, news reports about price-change announcements, and anecdotal information from our business contacts. Conceptually, one might think of this effort to distinguish transitory from persistent price changes as a more nuanced way of estimating the underlying inflation trend, analogous to the trend measures provided by more mechanical indicators such as trimmed-mean or weighted-median inflation rates.

      An accurate forecast of very near-term inflation is important not only for its own sake but also because it provides a better "jumping-off point" for the longer-term forecast. Because inflation continues to exhibit some inertia, improved near-term forecasts translate into more-accurate longer-term projections as well.

      For forecasting horizons beyond a quarter or two, detailed analyses of individual price components become less useful, and thus the staff's emphasis shifts to inflation's fundamental determinants. Food and energy inflation are forecasted separately from the core, using information from futures prices and other sources. However, forecasts of core inflation must take into account the extent to which food and energy costs are passed through to other prices.

      To project core inflation at longer-term horizons, the staff consults a range of econometric models. Most of the models used are based on versions of the new Keynesian Phillips curve, which links inflation to inflation expectations, the extent of economic slack, and indicators of supply shocks. Despite the common conceptual framework, the model specifications employed differ considerably in their details, including how lagged inflation enters the equation, how resource utilization is measured, and whether a survey-based measure of inflation expectations is included. In principle, formal econometric tests could determine how much weight should be put on the forecast of each model, but in practice the data do not permit sharp inferences; moreover, estimated forecasting equations may not reflect information about special factors affecting the outlook. Because of these considerations, as I have already noted, the staff's inflation forecasts inevitably reflect a substantial degree of expert judgment and the use of information not captured by the models.

      Another reason for the reliance on judgment in the forecasting process is the practical requirement that the forecast for inflation be consistent with the staff's overall view of the economy, including the forecasts for key economic variables such as wages, interest rates, and consumption spending. Achieving this consistency requires a thoughtful understanding of why sectoral forecasts may be at odds and how best to reconcile those differences. Again, in principle, consistency of sectoral forecasts could be ensured by estimating the inflation equation as part of a general equilibrium system. Indeed, considerable progress has been made in recent years, at the Board and elsewhere, in developing dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) models detailed enough for policy application. These models have become increasingly useful for policy analysis and for the simulation of alternative scenarios. They are likely to play a more significant role in the forecasting process over time as well, though, like other formal methods, they are unlikely to displace expert judgment.

      A potential drawback of the simple Phillips curve model for analyzing and forecasting inflation is that it does not explicitly incorporate the possible influence of labor costs on the inflation process. The Board's large macroeconomic simulation model, known as FRB/US, projects inflation through a system approach that captures the interaction of wage and price determination. Interestingly, however, the system approach does not seem to forecast price inflation as well as single-equation Phillips curve models do. This weaker performance appears to reflect, at least in part, the shortcomings of the available data on labor compensation. The two principal quarterly indicators of aggregate hourly compensation are the employment cost index (ECI) and nonfarm compensation per hour (CPH). Both are imperfect measures of the labor costs relevant to pricing decisions. For example, the ECI's fixed employment and occupation weights may not reflect changes in the labor market, and the ECI excludes stock options and similar forms of payment. CPH is volatile, perhaps in part because it measures stock options at exercise rather than when granted, and it is subject to substantial revisions. Moreover, these two hourly compensation measures often give contradictory signals. Despite these problems, labor market developments certainly influence how the staff and policymakers view the inflation process and inflation risks, illustrating yet another point in the forecasting process at which judgment must play an important role. In particular, in evaluating labor-market conditions and trends in labor costs, the staff takes note of a wide range of data, anecdotes, and other qualitative information as well as the official data on compensation.

      Overall, the Board staff's inflation forecasting has been remarkably good, at least compared with the available alternatives (Romer and Romer, 2000; Sims, 2002). To cite a recent study, Faust and Wright (2007) show that real-time staff forecasts of inflation reliably outperform statistical benchmarks at all horizons and that this advantage is not solely the result of the staff's expertise at estimating near-term inflation rates.

      To link this discussion of forecasting to the first portion of my remarks, I turn to the treatment of inflation expectations in staff forecasts. As I noted earlier, while inflation expectations doubtless are crucial determinants of observed inflation, measuring expectations and inferring just how they affect inflation are difficult tasks. A popular shortcut is to include lagged inflation terms in the Phillips curve equation; besides being a convenient means of capturing the inertial component in inflation, the estimated coefficients on lagged inflation almost certainly reflect to some degree the formation of inflation expectations and their influence on the inflation process. However, using lagged inflation as a proxy for inflation expectations has drawbacks, notably its susceptibility to the Lucas critique.4 The staff consequently analyzes a number of survey measures of inflation expectations. One question in choosing among measures of expectations is whether to focus on measures of short-term inflation expectations (say, twelve months ahead) or of longer-term expectations (five to ten years ahead). Generally, measures of longer-term inflation expectations, such as the five-to-ten-year expected inflation measures from the Michigan/Reuters survey of households and from the Survey of Professional Forecasters, seem to be better gauges of the expectations that influence wage- and price-setting behavior.

      The staff also looks at measures derived from comparing yields on nominal and inflation-indexed Treasury securities (the breakeven inflation rate). Measures of inflation compensation derived from the market for inflation-indexed securities are influenced by changes in inflation risk premiums and liquidity premiums, and analyses are constrained by the fact that these markets have been operating in the United States for only a relatively short period. Nevertheless, unlike survey measures, breakeven inflation rates are determined in a market in which investors back their views with real money. Moreover, breakeven measures of inflation expectations provide information on the expectations of a different group of agents--financial-market participants--which can be compared with the views of economists and consumers as represented by surveys.

      Measurement is only one aspect of understanding inflation expectations. We also need a better understanding of how inflation expectations affect actual inflation and of the factors that determine inflation expectations. I will say a few words about the latter issue in the context of the practical problems of forecasting and policy analysis faced by the staff of the Federal Reserve Board.

      Model-based simulations of the inflation process are useful tools for both forecasting and policy analysis. In conducting such simulations, the analyst must specify how inflation expectations are formed--in particular, how they react to actual changes in the economy and in policy. In most simulations of the FRB/US model, the public is assumed to update its inflation projections based on the historical relationship between inflation and other key economic variables. Essentially, this approach assumes that the public updates its inflation expectations in a sensible way based on economic developments but does not assume that the public has full knowledge of the underlying model of the economy, consistent with the structure of learning models (Brayton and others, 1997).

      Recent staff work at the Board has analyzed the implications of expanding the set of variables allowed to influence the public's long-term inflation expectations to include, among others, the federal funds rate.5 If the public's long-term inflation expectations are influenced directly by Fed actions, as this specification suggests, a number of interesting implications follow. One is that the output costs of disinflation may be lower than those suggested by reduced-form-type Phillips curves. Intuitively, if the Fed attempts to disinflate by raising the federal funds rate, the disinflationary effect will be felt not only through the usual output gap channel but also through a direct restraint on long-term inflation expectations. This interpretation is consistent with some analyses of the Volcker disinflation; although the costs of that disinflation were high, they were perhaps less than economists would have predicted in advance, given conventional estimates of the sacrifice ratio (Erceg and Levin, 2003).

      To be sure, this and similar analyses remain speculative. A good deal more must be done before such work proves a reliable basis for policy choices. Nevertheless, I hope this example illustrates for you the theme of my remarks, that a deeper understanding of the determinants and effects of the public's expectations of inflation could have significant practical payoffs.


      --------------------------------------------------------------------------------

      References

      Bernanke, Ben (2004). "Fedspeak," at the meetings of the American Economic Association, San Diego, California, January 3, 2004.

      Bils, Mark and Peter Klenow (2004). "Some Evidence on the Importance of Sticky Prices," Journal of Political Economy, vol. 112 (October), pp. 847-85.

      Bullard, James, and Kaushik Mitra (2002). "Learning about Monetary Policy Rules," Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 49(September), pp. 1105-29.

      Brayton, Flint, Eileen Mauskopf, David Reifschneider, Peter Tinsley, and John Williams (1997). "The Role of Expectations in the FRB/US Macroeconomic Model," Federal Reserve Bulletin, vol. 83(April), pp. 227-45.

      Carroll, Christopher D. (2003). "Macroeconomic Expectations of Households and Professional Forecasters," Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 118 (February), pp. 269-98.

      Cogley, Timothy (2005). "Changing Beliefs and the Term Structure of Interest Rates: Cross-Equation Restrictions with Drifting Parameters," Review of Economic Dynamics, vol. 8 (April), pp. 420-51.

      Cogley, Timothy, and Thomas J. Sargent (2007). "Inflation Gap Persistence in the U.S. (5.7 MB PDF)" University of California, Davis, working paper, January.

      Erceg, Christopher, and Andrew Levin (2003). "Imperfect Credibility and Inflation Persistence," Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 50 (May), pp. 915-44.

      Faust, Jon, and Jonathan H. Wright (2007). "Comparing Greenbook and Reduced Form Forecasts Using a Large Realtime Dataset (259 KB PDF)," Johns Hopkins University and Board of Governors, working paper.

      Gaspar, Vitor, Frank Smets, and David Vestin (2006). "Adaptive Learning, Persistence, and Optimal Monetary Policy," Journal of the European Economic Association, vol. 4 (April-May), pp. 376-85.

      Gordon, Robert J. (2007). "Phillips Curve Specification and the Decline in U.S. Output and Inflation Volatility," presented at the Symposium on The Phillips Curve and the Natural Rate of Unemployment, Institut für Weltwirtschaft, Kiel, Germany, June 3-4.

      Gürkaynak, Refet, Brian Sack, and Eric Swanson (2005). "The Sensitivity of Long-term Interest Rates to Economic News: Evidence and Implications for Macroeconomic Models," American Economic Review, vol. 95 (March), pp. 425-36.

      Hooker, Mark (2002). "Are Oil Shocks Inflationary? Asymmetric and Nonlinear Specifications versus Changes in Regime," Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, vol. 34 (May), pp. 540-61.

      Kozicki, Sharon, and Peter Tinsley (2001). "Shifting Endpoints in the Term Structure of Interest Rates," Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 47(June), pp. 613-52.

      Levin, Andrew, Fabio Natalucci, and Jeremy Piger (2004). "The Macroeconomic Effects of Inflation Targeting (406 KB PDF)," Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Review, vol. 86 (July), pp. 51-80.

      Mankiw, N. Gregory, Ricardo Reis, and Justin Wolfers (2003). "Disagreement about Inflation Expectations," NBER Macroeconomics Annual, pp. 209-248.

      Mishkin, Frederic S. (2007). "Inflation Dynamics," National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper no. 13147, June.

      Nakamura, Emi, and Jon Steinsson (2007). "Five Facts About Prices: A Reevaluation of Menu Cost Models (577 KB PDF)," Harvard University, working paper, May.

      Nason, James (2006). "Instability in U.S. Inflation: 1967-2005," Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, Economic Review, vol. 91 (Second Quarter), pp. 39-59.

      Orphanides, Athanasios, and John C. Williams (2005). "Inflation Scares and Forecast-based Monetary Policy," Review of Economic Dynamics, vol. 8 (April), pp. 498-527.

      Roberts, John (2006). "Monetary Policy and Inflation Dynamics," International Journal of Central Banking, vol. 2 (September), pp. 193-230.

      Romer, Christina, and David Romer (2000). "Federal Reserve Information and the Behavior of Interest Rates," American Economic Review, vol. 90 (June), pp. 429-57.

      Rudebusch, Glenn, and Tao Wu (2003). "A Macro-Finance Model of the Term Structure, Monetary Policy, and the Economy (562 KB PDF)," Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper 2003-17, September.

      Sargent, Thomas J. (1999). The Conquest of American Inflation. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.

      Sims, Christopher (2002). "The Role of Models and Probabilities in the Monetary Policy Process," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, vol. 2, pp. 1-40.

      Stock, James, and Mark Watson (2007). "Why Has U.S. Inflation Become Harder to Forecast?" Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, vol. 39 (February), pp. 3-34.


      --------------------------------------------------------------------------------

      Footnotes

      1. Roberts (2006) provides a recent overview. He attributes most of the "flattening" of the Phillips curve to changes in the conduct of monetary policy.See also Nason (2006). Gordon (2007) provides an opposing view.Return to text

      2. Stock and Watson assume that transitory shocks last only one quarter. Cogley and Sargent (2007) explore the Stock-Watson specification in more detail, arguing that the transitory component of inflation is best modeled as having somewhat greater persistence. Return to text

      3. A particularly valuable part of the paper is a case study of the evolution of expectations during the Volcker disinflation of 1979-1982. Histograms of the quarterly range of inflation expectations show only a very gradual adjustment of inflation expectations as the disinflation proceeded, with significant reductions in expectations occurring only in the third year of the disinflation. Moreover, the range of disagreement widened (and even became somewhat bimodal) as individual respondents evidently differed in their willingness to accept the Fed"s declared commitment to reducing inflation as being a true break from the past. Capturing this behavior in a formal model would be challenging but worthwhile. Return to text

      4. The Lucas critique holds that reduced-form empirical relationships estimated on historical data may break down when policies change. Return to text

      5. In this empirical work, the public"s long-run inflation expectations are proxied for by the long-run inflation projections taken from the Survey of Professional Forecasters (Mishkin, 2007). Return to text

      Comment


      • #4
        Re: Treasurys Up Sharply on Housing Market Concerns

        I thought Bernie was out of the Chicago school, this reads more like a behaviorist. Lots of ways to manage behavior, none of which has anything to do with interest rates.

        Still, I think we can agree that, at a minimum, the opposite proposition--that inflationary policies promote employment growth in the long run--has been entirely discredited and, indeed, that policies based on this proposition have led to very bad outcomes whenever they have been applied.

        WTF does that mean?
        the policymakers' objective function is not fully known by private agents.

        Proving once again that it's the Fed's job to get the maximum number of investors/bagholders betting the wrong direction.


        I do think I'd be a bit concerned if I was ine changing my long term inflation expectations and had my investments geared up that way as well. Bernieboy does seem to imply that Wall Street not the Fed, sets the price. If the '87 market crash was saved by a $30 million futures bet in the market, something similiar can occur with the bet being the other direction today.
        "Men, it has been well said, think in herds; it will be seen that they go mad in herds, while they only recover their senses slowly, and one by one."
        - Charles Mackay

        Comment


        • #5
          Re: Treasurys Up Sharply on Housing Market Concerns

          Originally posted by Tet
          I do think I'd be a bit concerned if I was ine changing my long term inflation expectations and had my investments geared up that way as well. Bernieboy does seem to imply that Wall Street not the Fed, sets the price. If the '87 market crash was saved by a $30 million futures bet in the market, something similiar can occur with the bet being the other direction today.
          LOL, in a way they do, Wall Street is were the illusion is manufactured for massive consumption...

          Comment


          • #6
            Re: Treasurys Up Sharply on Housing Market Concerns

            Originally posted by Sapiens View Post
            LOL, in a way they do, Wall Street is were the illusion is manufactured for massive consumption...
            I'm getting the impression that Bernieboy believes Greed causes inflation and Fear causes deflation. I can speak from first hand experience that there is nothing like a good asshanding to change one's inflationary/greed expectations from the market to one of fear/deflation. Inflation/greed seems to have been removed from the housing market lately. I would think one should look for similar assets selling at 30-year highs to see if inflation/greed isn't taken out of those assets as well. Oil comes to mind here, same with other commodities. TWT, hopefully Ben moving forward will be easier to read than Sir Alan.
            "Men, it has been well said, think in herds; it will be seen that they go mad in herds, while they only recover their senses slowly, and one by one."
            - Charles Mackay

            Comment


            • #7
              Re: Treasurys Up Sharply on Housing Market Concerns

              Originally posted by Sapiens View Post
              Like Fred previously posted, once you understand the game all seems anticlimactic when it unfolds...Yawn.


              Another Yawn:
              http://www.moodys.com/cust/default.asp




              Moody's Downgrades Subprime First-Lien RMBS



              New York, July 10, 2007 -- Moody's Investors Service today announced negative rating actions on 431 securities originated in 2006 and backed by subprime first lien mortgage loans. The negative rating actions affect securities with an original face value of over $5.2 billion, representing 1.2% of the dollar volume and 6.8% of the securities rated by Moody's in 2006 that were backed by subprime first lien loans.

              Of the 431 rating actions taken today, Moody's downgraded 399 securities and placed an additional 32 securities on review for possible downgrade. One of the downgraded securities remains on review for possible further downgrade. The vast majority of rating actions taken today impacted securities originally rated Baa or lower. The 239 securities originally rated Baa on which action was taken represented 19% of the total number of Baa ratings issued in 2006; the 185 securities originally rated Ba on which action was taken represented 42% of the total number of Ba ratings issued in 2006; and, the 7 securities originally rated A on which action was taken represented 0.6% of the total number of A ratings issued in 2006. No action was taken on securities rated Aaa or Aa.

              Rating Actions Reflect Rigorous Review of All 2006 Subprime RMBS Deals

              Nicolas Weill, Chief Credit Officer of Moody's Structured Finance Group, said, "Moody's has been closely monitoring all subprime RMBS securities as part of our ongoing ratings process, and we began taking rating actions on securities issued in 2006 and backed by poorly performing pools of subprime mortgage loans in November 2006. Over the past three months, Moody's has surveyed servicers, originators, intermediaries and other market participants to get their perspective on the drivers of the 2006 vintage performance and their expectations about future losses. Based on our analysis of pool performance, we undertook a rigorous examination of all 2006 subprime RMBS deals -- including deals backed by both first lien and second lien loans. The rating actions announced today -- as well as those announced on June 15 -- are the result of that review."

              Overview of Factors Driving Rating Actions

              Recent data shows that the first lien subprime mortgage loans securitized in 2006 have delinquency rates that are higher than original expectations. Those loans were originated in an environment of aggressive underwriting. This aggressive underwriting combined with prolonged, slowing home price appreciation has caused significant loan performance deterioration and is the primary factor in these rating actions. In addition, Moody's analysis shows that the transactions backed by collateral originated by Fremont Investment & Loan, Long Beach Mortgage Company, New Century Mortgage Corporation and WMC Mortgage Corp. have been performing below the average of the 2006 vintage and represent about 60% of the rating actions taken today.

              Additional Findings From Moody's Review of 2006 Subprime RMBS First Lien Deals

              Moody's has noted a persistent negative trend in severe delinquencies for first lien subprime mortgage loans securitized in 2006. For example, the 90+ day delinquency rate for loans securitized in 2006 has increased from 7.9% in March 2007 to 10.8% in May 2007. However, losses have remained relatively low, with the May cumulative loss rate reaching only 0.30%.

              As part of the recently completed review of all 2006 subprime RMBS, Moody's said it examined the portion of each pool that was severely delinquent -- that is, over 90 days past due, in foreclosure or held as "real estate owned" -- and assessed the amount of credit enhancement available to the rated tranches in the form of subordination and excess spread. "Early defaulting borrowers often exhibit distinct characteristics: they are more likely to be first-time home buyers, speculators, or are over-leveraged or have 80%-20% first-second lien loan combinations," said Weill. Consequently, the early defaulters may exhibit different behavior than other borrowers in the pool. Those borrowers may face other challenges in the next few months when rate and payment resets take effect, especially in the absence of effective loan modifications.

              In analyzing loans that are severely delinquent, Moody's said it considered a number of scenarios based on various assumptions about the percentage of currently delinquent loans that would eventually default (the "roll rate") and the expected severity of loss given default. The roll rates used were: for over 90 days delinquent: 50%, 75% and 90%; for those loans in foreclosure and held as real estate owned: 95% and 100%. While these roll rates are higher than those that have been realized historically, Moody's believes that these loans, with their high vacancy rates and high "no contact" rates, are more likely to default than other subprime loans.

              The severity rates Moody's assumed ranged from 25%-30% (in particular, for deals with strong coverage from mortgage insurance), to 40% (for most originators), to 50% for originators whose mortgage assets are revealing particularly high severe delinquency rates.

              For the portion of each pool that is not severely delinquent, Moody's increased its original loss expectations for the pool by a stress factor of 20% which is consistent with the increased loss expectations that the rating agency published in its March 2007 report: "Challenging Times for the US Subprime Mortgage Market."

              While we considered both the projected losses associated with the seriously delinquent loans (the "pipeline losses") as well as the projected losses associated with the remaining portion of the pool, we gave more weight to the pipeline losses.

              Moody's invites you to participate in a teleconference on Thursday, 12 July 2007 at 10:00 EST / 15:00 BST (local London time) to discuss these actions. The call will be hosted by Richard Cantor, Team Managing Director, Credit Policy Research Group; Nicolas Weill, Team Managing Director and Chief Credit Officer, Asset Finance; and John Park, Senior Vice President, Derivatives Monitoring. Details of the call are as follows:

              US and Canada +1 800.795.1259
              All Others: +1 785.832.0301
              Passcode: moodys


              For details on the conference call, as well as Moody's published research on the subprime market, go to www.moodys.com/subprime. Please contact Moody's Client Service Desk at +1.212.553.1658 with any other questions.

              A press release detailing the specific securities whose ratings were affected has been released and is available on moodys.com.

              Comment


              • #8
                Re: Treasurys Up Sharply on Housing Market Concerns

                http://www.bloomberg.com/apps/news?p...3wk&refer=home

                Moody's Lowers Ratings on Subprime Bonds, S&P May Cut (Update1)

                By Mark Pittman
                July 10 (Bloomberg) -- Moody's Investors Service lowered the credit ratings on $5.2 billion of bonds backed by subprime mortgages and Standard & Poor's said it may cut $12 billion of securities after criticism they waited too long to respond to rising home-loan defaults.
                So they all come out at once?

                `Why Now?'
                ``I'd like to know: Why now?'' Steven Eisman, a portfolio manager at Frontpoint Partners in New York said on a conference call hosted by S&P to discuss the possible ratings changes. ``The news has been out on subprime now for many, many months. The delinquencies have been a disaster for many, many months. The ratings have been called into question for many, many months. I'd like to know why you're making this move today instead of many months ago.''
                Tom Warrack, an S&P managing director, said it takes time for performance to show through. ``We have been surveilling these deals actively on a regular basis beginning in 2005 and 2006,'' Warrack said on the call. ``We believe that the performance that we've been able to observe now warrants action.''
                In response to the investor criticism, executives at S&P, Moody's and Fitch have said they were waiting until foreclosure sales of homes proved that the collateral backing the bonds has declined enough to create losses.
                "warrants action" it's cover your ass time and it's a little late.

                Comment


                • #9
                  Treasurys Up Sharply and just by coincidence there are Housing Market Concerns

                  Treasurys Up Sharply and just by coincidence there are Housing Market Concerns

                  IMHO that would be a better way to phrase the situation because In today's world the 2 are not necessarily connected.

                  Since a huge chunk of the T-bill market, the Central Bankers, don't care one whit about the US housing market

                  I bet another huge chunk of the Tbill market is the private money that is betting with the Central Banks, thinking that they cannot beat the CBs, might as well go along with a trade that makes money based on the CB actions.

                  That's a lot of money that is politically driven and is not really profit-seeking (notwithstanding the government equity funds)

                  Comment


                  • #10
                    Re: Treasurys Up Sharply on Housing Market Concerns

                    In Laymans terms?
                    Mega

                    Comment


                    • #11
                      Re: Treasurys Up Sharply and just by coincidence there are Housing Market Concerns

                      Originally posted by Spartacus View Post
                      Treasurys Up Sharply and just by coincidence there are Housing Market Concerns

                      IMHO that would be a better way to phrase the situation because In today's world the 2 are not necessarily connected.
                      Supporting facts and basis for your opinion, please.

                      Originally posted by Spartacus View Post
                      Since a huge chunk of the T-bill market, the Central Bankers, don't care one whit about the US housing market

                      I bet another huge chunk of the Tbill market is the private money that is betting with the Central Banks, thinking that they cannot beat the CBs, might as well go along with a trade that makes money based on the CB actions.

                      That's a lot of money that is politically driven and is not really profit-seeking (notwithstanding the government equity funds)
                      A contradiction, most sovereign funds are directed by their respective CB. Treasuries are up because private funds are seeking safety.

                      Comment


                      • #12
                        Re: Treasurys Up Sharply on Housing Market Concerns

                        Originally posted by Mega View Post
                        In Laymans terms?
                        Mega
                        The housing market has been sending doom signals for ages and ages. So why would treasuries react NOW? To news that was old eons ago?

                        the original post was

                        used-to-be-the-cause ----> effect

                        (note the unbroken line)

                        This may have been true when the people in the bond markets (the long lost Bond Vigilantes of myth and legend) were profit-seeking animals.

                        Ain't nonesuch thing in these parts nomore . What I suggest is

                        used-to-be-the-cause -------X---X---X--> effect <------- real-new-cause

                        where "real-new-cause" is unknown

                        Comment


                        • #13
                          Re: Treasurys Up Sharply and just by coincidence there are Housing Market Concerns

                          Originally posted by Sapiens View Post
                          Supporting facts and basis for your opinion, please.
                          No facts, sorry - I openly, loudly and volubly admit I'm way short on facts and long on supposition on this one.

                          The main idea being that the housing news has been heading south for a long, LONG time - the villain done died a long time ago - he can't have done any recent devilry. Why lay the blame for anything current at the feet of a rotting carcass, one that's been dead a while?

                          Surely the stench couldn't have taken a quantum leap in the last little while.

                          Comment


                          • #14
                            Re: Treasurys Up Sharply on Housing Market Concerns

                            Originally posted by Spartacus View Post
                            The housing market has been sending doom signals for ages and ages. So why would treasuries react NOW? To news that was old eons ago?

                            the original post was

                            used-to-be-the-cause ----> effect

                            (note the unbroken line)

                            This may have been true when the people in the bond markets (the long lost Bond Vigilantes of myth and legend) were profit-seeking animals.

                            Ain't nonesuch thing in these parts nomore . What I suggest is

                            used-to-be-the-cause -------X---X---X--> effect <------- real-new-cause

                            where "real-new-cause" is unknown

                            A.....I see !
                            Thanks
                            Mega

                            Comment


                            • #15
                              Re: Treasurys Up Sharply and just by coincidence there are Housing Market Concerns

                              Looks like I was completely wrong here, specifically my theory that the housing bubble bust, and all the paper derived therefrom had already been discounted.

                              The news of the last couple of days - the recent ABX declines, Bear Stearns telling clients they've lost all their money in the 2 hedge funds - one can only conclude that the bad news was NOT discounted.

                              Everyone who should have been discounting, it seems, thought they could whistle past the graveyard.


                              Originally posted by Sapiens View Post
                              Supporting facts and basis for your opinion, please.



                              A contradiction, most sovereign funds are directed by their respective CB. Treasuries are up because private funds are seeking safety.

                              Comment

                              Working...
                              X