Re: Inflation Peaks/Real-gdp Peaks/Interest Rates Peak
xxxxxxxxxxxxx
xxxxxxxxxxxxx
Stephen Cecchetti 13 August 2007 | Print Email Comment Republish |
Here are the basic how's and why's of what the Fed has been doing to calm financial markets Let’s start with the facts: On Thursday 9 August 2007 the Federal Reserve’s Open Market Trading Desk (the “Desk”) injected $24 billion into the U.S. banking system. This was done in two equal size operations, one at 8:25am and a second 70 minutes later at 9:35am.1 On Friday 10 August 2007, the Desk was in the market three times (8:25am, 10:55am, and 1:50pm) putting in a total of $38 billion. The Fed’s operations came on the heels of two even larger injections by the ECB in Frankfurt. On Thursday morning the European Central Bank (ECB) in Frankfurt, Germany had put nearly €95 billion ($130 billion) into European financial institutions, followed by a somewhat smaller operation of €61 billion ($83.6 billion) on Friday. How is this actually done? What are the mechanics of the transactions? In all of these cases, the funds were put into the banking system using what are called “repurchase agreements” or “repos” for short. Here’s a dictionary-style description: A repurchase agreement is a short-term collateralised loan in which a security is exchanged for cash, with the agreement that the parties will reverse the transaction on a specific future date at an agreed-upon price, as soon as the next day. For example, a bank that has a U.S. Treasury bill might need cash, while a pension fund might have cash that it doesn’t need overnight. Through a repurchase agreement, the bank would give the T-bill to the pension fund in exchange for cash, agreeing to buy it back at the original price – repurchase it – with interest the next day. In short, the bank gets an overnight loan and the pension fund gets some extra interest. The details are shown in the figure below. The mechanics of an Overnight Repurchase Agreement Source: Cecchetti, Money, Banking, and Financial Markets 2nd Edition, New York: McGraw-Hill Irwin, 2009, pg. 278 The easiest way to think about a repo is as an overnight mortgage. In the same way that you pledge your house to the bank in exchange for a loan, a financial institution pledges a bond to the Fed in exchange for funds. The Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Open Market Desk engages in repurchase agreements every morning (the exact time varies). The quantities normally range from $2 billion to $20 billion.2 Most of them are overnight, but it is standard to engage in repos that are as long as 14 days. The $35 billion on Friday 10 August 2007 was the largest since those in the aftermath of the 9/11 terrorist attacks. (The record is $81.25 billion on 14 September 2001.) What happens if the bonds used in the repo fall in value overnight? When the Fed engages in a repo, the bank (or securities dealer) on the other side – what is called the “counterparty” – agrees to repurchase the security at a fixed price regardless of what happens in the markets.3 It is these banks who benefit from the gains and suffer the losses when the prices move. The only risk the Fed faces is that the counterparty in a repo goes bankrupt and can’t make good on the promise. Given that these are very large banks, and that the repos are very short term, this is an incredibly unlikely event. Does this have any impact on the government’s budget deficit? No. Central bank operations have nothing to do with fiscal policy -- federal government tax, expenditure and debt management policies – they are all about the interest rate and the quantity of reserves in the banking system. The Federal Reserve is the Federal Government's banker – accepting and making payments, issuing debt when they want, etc. – but they are not connected in any material way. (I'm simplifying slightly here, as there is a very slight and esoteric connection.) If the Fed has $35 billion to help the financial system, why can’t they use some of their money to help the poor? The Fed isn’t spending the money on bailing out banks, hedge funds, or helping rich people. It is making fully-collateralised loans that will be repaid the next day (or week). So, while it’s putting the funds in today, it’s taking them out almost immediately. If, instead, the Fed were to take $35 billion in $20 bills and go hand them out to the needy, this would be a permanent increase in the quantity of money in circulation. More money in the long run means higher prices – and that’s inflation. What is liquidity and why is it so important? The publicly stated rationale for these large interventions is that liquidity dried up. Unfortunately, liquidity is one of those terms that means different things to different people. In the glossary to my Money and Banking textbook, I define liquidity as “the ease with which an asset can be turned into a means of payment such as money.” That is, when an asset is liquid it is easy to sell large quantities without moving market prices. When something is illiquid, it is hard to sell People don’t want to buy things that they can’t sell easily. If they are worried that a bond they are considering buying may be difficult or expensive to sell, they will lower the price they are willing to pay, assuming they are still willing to buy it at all. For financial markets to function well, it must be cheap and easy to both buy and sell securities. When market liquidity dries up, the financial markets stop functioning This form of liquidity might be better labeled “market liquidity” as distinct from what I would call “lending liquidity.” Lending liquidity is the term I attach to the concept that was in the news until recently. You may recall reading or hearing about “enormous amounts of liquidity sloshing around the system.” When people said this, what they meant (I think) is that loan supply was plentiful so it was easy to borrow at favourable rates. Put differently (and using technical jargon), it meant that risk spreads were low and insensitive to a borrower’s balance sheet position – that the risk premium a borrower paid was small and did not increase with additional borrowing, which should be riskier. Fall 1998 was the last time market liquidity dried up to a greater extent than we observe today. Then it was difficult even to trade US Treasury securities – usually the most liquid financial market there is.4 So far, things are nowhere near that bad. In fact, with few exceptions, markets still seem to be operating normally. $35 billion seems like quite a bit of money. Is it? To put the number into perspective, we have to understand what these funds are used for. When the Fed injects “money” into the financial system, what it does is create balances in something called “reserve accounts”. That’s where the money goes. Commercial banks have deposit accounts at the Fed (you and I can’t have one). Those are the bank’s checking accounts, with the exception that they don’t pay interest. Because there is no interest paid on reserve balances, banks try to economise on the quantities. Banks hold reserves at the Fed for three primary reasons: (1) They are required to hold them. (2) They need it to do business, so they can meet customer demands for withdrawals and they can make payments to other banks. (3) It is prudent to do so; reserves act as the bank’s emergency fund – they are always ready just in case disaster strikes. So, is $35 billion a big number or not? Here are three numbers we could use to get some sense:
Finally, note the rather amazing fact that during normal times the banking system uses $12 billion to engage in $4 trillion in daily transactions. That is, on average a dollar in a reserve account is used more than 300 times PER DAY. Because reserves do not pay interest, banks have a big incentive to economise on their use – this is pretty efficient. (This is also the reason that excess reserves are so low.) That banks do this every day suggests that they know how to do it; but the fact that they use the funds so many times means that if anyone starts hoarding reserves, there is the potential to disrupt the system. The conclusion is that the $35 billion is a very big number – it is three times the normal level of reserves that banks hold. Why did they need it? Why did the banks need this money? It is easy to explain why the Fed used open market operations to add $81.25 billion on 14 September 2001 in the aftermath of the 9/11 terrorist attacks. People’s inability to reach their offices in downtown New York had closed some very large banks. Though those banks could still receive payments from other banks, they couldn’t make any payments to anyone else. Funds were flowing into a few huge reserve accounts, but nothing was coming out. Some banks were sucking up the lifeblood of the financial system. Last week the trigger seems to have been the continued fall in the value of certain mortgage-backed securities. Mortgage backed securities bundle a large number of mortgages together into a pool in which shares are then sold. The owners of these securities receive a share of the payments made by the homeowners who borrowed the funds. The pools create a form of insurance. In the same way that automobile insurance companies know what fraction of the insured will have collisions (but not exactly which individuals), pools of mortgages mean investors can predict the quantity of defaults and the repayment rates. There are numerous types of mortgage-backed securities, but the ones that have run into difficulty are in what is called the “subprime” segment of the market. Subprime borrowers are basically people with poor credit who cannot qualify for a standard mortgage. Making loans to these people is known to be risky. And when things are risky, sometimes they don’t work out. That’s what happened. But up to now, the problems in the subprime mortgage market are relatively small. Currently, losses are estimated to be at most $35 billion – equivalent to a stock market decline of about 0.2%. (Last week the value of stocks traded in US markets were down a not terribly unusual 1.5%, or 7 times the total expected decline in the value of these mortgages). What’s happened is that problems in this one, relatively small part of the financial system been seeping into the rest of the market. When people see that they have underestimated the risks in one place, they start to question their ability to accurately evaluate risks everywhere else. Then two things happen. First, the prices of risky financial assets fall. Risk requires compensation, and the more risk there is, the more compensation. Second, people flee risky stuff that they find it hard to evaluate and put their money in safe assets – what’s called a “flight to quality.” The flight to quality is reflected in an increase in prices of U.S. Treasury securities and an influx of funds into the banking system. So, the first reason the banks need the reserves is to serve the customers that have brought money into their deposit accounts. But individuals are not the only ones who have reduced their tolerance for risk. Bankers have, too. Bankers’ reduced risk tolerance shows up in two important ways, both of which result in higher demand for reserve balances. The first is that they simply want a bigger cushion against the possibility of losses. That’s pretty simple. The second reason bankers need more reserves is that they have become less willing to lend their reserves to other banks. There is a huge daily interbank market for overnight loans. It’s called the “federal funds market” and the interest rate charged on those overnight loans is the “federal funds rate.” The federal funds rate is the rate targeted by the Federal Reserve.6 On a normal day (which Thursday and Friday of last week were not) banks are willing to make loans early in the day even if it means temporarily overdrawing their accounts. (Yes, they are allowed to do that.) Banks that are overdrawn in the morning figure that if they don’t receive payments to bring their reserve accounts back into positive territory by the end of the day, they can always go out and borrow it back. Well, it appears that last week banks were not willing to behave this way and the result was that it was very difficult to borrow late in the day. The bottom line of this very long-winded explanation is that the banks wanted to hold substantially higher level of reserves. Keeping the federal funds rate at its target level of 5.25% – that’s what the Open Market Desk at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York is supposed to do every day – meant engaging in huge operations. I’ve heard that the Fed’s operation had something to do with mortgages. Did it? Yes it did. On Friday 10 August the Fed accepted mortgage-backed securities as collateral for the entirety of the $35 billion in repos it engaged in that day. Importantly, though, they did not accept just any mortgage-backed securities. They only allowed dealers to pledge mortgage-backed securities issued or fully guaranteed by federal agencies. Two comments are important here. First, this is not new. The willingness to accept mortgage-backed securities as collateral in repos goes back to changes made in advance of Y2K. At the time there were concerns about being able to get funds into the financial system quickly, and this is one of the changes made. Since then, the Fed has taken mortgage-backed securities at nearly the same rate they have taken agency securities. Nevertheless, the way in which the Fed chose to do this is notable. Normally, when the Fed sends out a message, they tell dealers exactly what they want in collateral. Each of the three categories is treated separately. So, it is common for the Desk to send out a message that they are willing to accept only Treasury securities. Alternatively, they might send out a message that they will accept all three types – Treasury, agency and mortgage-backed – in three separate operations. What the Desk did on Friday is send out a message that said they would take whatever the dealers wanted to deliver. Since mortgage-backed securities are the cheapest to deliver (they have the lowest price in the market), that’s what came in. My speculation is that the Fed did this to demonstrate to the markets that they believe mortgage-backed securities are good as collateral. They were trying get financial market participants to value mortgage pools sensibly. Who decides to do this? A number of people are involved in deciding the quantity of a daily open market operation. On a normal day there isn’t much to decide. The Desk staff makes a recommendation in a conference call and the participants agree. (Having listened in on these calls, I can attest to the fact that they are normally not very interesting.) Last week was obviously not normal. While I doubt that the entire Federal Open Market Committee decided on the action, they may have been consulted through a conference call. My guess is that Chairman Bernanke and New York Fed President Geithner had a say. What I can be sure of is that the decision was made by the Federal Reserve, not by the Secretary of the Treasury or the President of the United States. Why is this happening now? It is natural to ask whether there is some specific reason for these events to occur right now. Can we identify a specific trigger? While we can see something that has happened, as I suggested earlier there has been no fundamental deterioration in economic conditions. In fact, in the United States there was no economic data released on Thursday 9 August 2007. So, it isn’t that people suddenly changed their view of the future. Instead, what happened was analogous to a bank run. Bank runs can be the result of either real or imagined problems. Here’s how it works. Most people, even fairly sophisticated investors, are not in a position to assess the quality of the assets on a financial institution’s balance sheet. In fact, most people don’t even know what those assets are. So when we learn that one bank is in trouble, investors begin to worry about all financial institutions and investors start to flee. The inability to accurately value assets leads to a strong shift toward high-quality securities like Treasury bonds. Thinking about it this way, there are two events that may have precipitated this. The first was the announcement on 2 August that the German bank, IKB Deutsche Industriebank AG, was in trouble because of investment in US subprime loans. And then, on Wednesday, that one of Europe’s largest banks, BNP Paribas, had three funds with similar problems. Financial market participants’ response was to reduce their exposure to risky investments under the assumption that they could not properly assess the risks. That’s exactly analogous to a bank run. It is impossible to predict the exact timing of something like that. Does this have anything to do with discount lending? For those of you who have seen (and heard) Jim Cramer’s diatribe on CNBC on Monday 3 August,7 you may be wondering about discount lending. Here’s the deal. The Fed has a standing offer to lend to banks (so long as they have collateral to pledge for the loan) at a rate that is 1 percentage point above the federal funds rate target of 5.25%. So, today a bank can borrow from the Fed at 6.25%. Banks, not the Fed, decide when to request a discount loan. The borrowed funds are deposited into the bank’s reserve account and can be loaned out to other banks. While we do not know for sure, it seems unlikely that discount lending increased much last week. The reason is that banks always have the option of borrowing from other banks at the federal funds rate, and the Federal Reserve Bank of New York reports that the highest rate charged for an overnight interbank loan late last week was 6%.8 I seriously doubt that a bank would borrow from the Fed at 6.25% when they can borrow more cheaply from another bank. I would guess that Cramer was really arguing for an interest rate cut. It’s hard to see why that’s necessary at the moment. If you can’t buy and sell the securities you own, you probably don’t care if the cost of funds is 5.25% or 4.25%, or whatever. The European Central Bank’s operation was much larger than the Fed’s. Is there a reason? The details of the European Central Bank’s (ECB) operating procedures are very different from those of the Fed, and I won’t go into the details here. Nevertheless, I can provide the simplest explanation for the size the ECB’s operation. When the ECB announced its intention to provide funds on Thursday 9 August 2007 (a day they would not normally operate at all) they said that they would accept all bids at or above their 4% target. The result was that banks asked for and received €95 billion ($130 billion). Unlike the US, where banks are not paid any interest on their excess reserves holdings, in Europe a bank that has excess can redeposit it at the ECB at a 3% interest rate. That makes it far cheaper for European banks to err on the holding of too high a level of reserve balances. Now, put yourself in the position of a European bank. Maybe you know something about what’s going on, maybe you don’t. In either case, when the ECB says that they are going to give you as much as you want on a day when they normally do nothing, you have to wonder what they know that you don’t. Footnotes 1 You can find all of the details by looking at the historical data on the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s website starting at http://www.newyorkfed.org/markets/omo/dmm/temp.cfm. Every transaction is posted shortly after it is completed. 2 The Desk puts out a call for bids, usually stating the term of the repo and the type of collateral that they will accept. Banks and securities dealers submit their offers – quantities and prices – and then the Manager at the New York Fed decides how much to accept. There are three types of collateral: US Treasury Securities, US Agency Securities (issued by people like Fannie Mae and the Small Business Administration), and Mortgage-backed Securities. Offers average roughly 5 times what’s accepted for Treasury securities, 10 times for Agency securities, and 15 times for Mortgage-backed. 3 The Fed only engages in transactions with 21 “primary dealers.” Primary dealers agree to make bids or offers when the Fed conducts open market operations, provide information to the Fed's open market trading desk, and to actively participate in US Treasury securities auctions when the bonds, notes, and bills are initially sold. 4 We can get some sense of the operation of a market by looking at the behavior of securities dealers who both buy and sell. When a market operates normally, the difference between the price they are bidding to buy and the one they are asking to sell – the bid/ask spread – is very small and they are willing to quote a single price for a large quantity. In the fall of 1998 there was a brief period when the bid/ask spread for US Treasury bonds was 10 times normal and the quantity for which dealers were willing to hold the price was one-tenth normal. 5 If you want to know more, start at www.federalreserve.gov/paymentsystems/fedwire/default.htm. 6 When the Federal Open Market Committee “sets the interest rate” they are really instructing the Open Market Desk to try and keep the federal funds rate determined by banks in the market for overnight loans near a specific target. The Desk does this by supplying the quantity of reserves they believe the banking system will want at that target rate. For somewhat complex reasons, the Fed does not actually determine the rate. |
Comment