Inflation targeting has become the predominant monetary policy strategy in recent years. Although neither the Fed nor the ECB are inflation targeters, they too have implicitly adopted many aspects of the inflation targeting framework.
The alleged success of inflation targeting in bringing down inflation and inflation expectations is probably not due to the inflation targeting strategy itself, but first of all to globalization, in particular the integration of China into the world economy, which resulted in persistent downward pressure on goods prices in recent years. A second reason for the reduction in inflation was probably the concurrent granting of independence to central banks which hitherto had been part of the finance ministries. Interestingly, a recent ECB Working Paper (”Global Inflation”) finds that one common factor accounts for 70% of the variance of inflation in industrial countries, inflation targeting or not.
Although inflation targeting is consistent and beautiful in theory, in practice, it suffers from serious shortcomings.
Sometime at the beginning of the 20th century, it was agreed that the most suitable measure of prices for monetary policy purposes is the consumer prices index. Consumer prices indeed have some attractive features: they directly affect most citizens, they are easy to gather, quickly available and are not revised. However, consumer prices are just a small subset of all prices in an economy, and therefore far from a comprehensive measure of “prices”. Not least Alchian and Klein (1973, “On a Correct Measure of Inflation”, JMCB) challenged (unsuccessfully) the use of consumer prices for monetary policy purposes.
The technical simplification soon took a life of it’s own, and in the minds of people, “consumer prices” became equivalent to “prices”. For example, most of today’s economics textbooks assume right from the start that the consumer price level is the one and only aggregate price level in an economy. People nowadays use the term inflation when in fact they mean consumer price inflation, the quantity theory of money is being (mis)interpreted such that money affects consumer prices, and Milton Friedman is (mis)understood as claiming that consumer price inflation is always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon.
Due to this subtle change of meaning, central banks, correctly wishing to provide price stability, wrongly restrict their focus on consumer prices. Unfortunately, money does not care about that change in semantics - it still affects all prices, including non-consumer goods prices, commodities, real estate, stocks, bonds and exchange rates. Not only has that been forgotten; central banks nowadays actually even deny responsibility for other prices than consumer prices.
In the face of a large positive supply shock from globalization, consumer prices should have been allowed to fall in recent years. By targeting a positive consumer price inflation rate, monetary policy has been too expansionary when it comes to other prices. Central banks have thus triggered a tsunami of liquidity and credit, which, probably some day soon, will come home to roost.
Don’t get me wrong: the idea of inflation targeting, namely stabilizing prices, is great. The original sin is the narrow focus on consumer prices. I don’t pretend to know how a better monetary policy strategy should look like. However, I suggest to look back into history for other viable monetary arrangements. Many clever people in the past must have had a reason when advocating to include monetary or credit aggregates into a monetary policy strategy, or to peg a currency to some asset which cannot be inflated at will, such as gold.
From: www.economicreason.com
The alleged success of inflation targeting in bringing down inflation and inflation expectations is probably not due to the inflation targeting strategy itself, but first of all to globalization, in particular the integration of China into the world economy, which resulted in persistent downward pressure on goods prices in recent years. A second reason for the reduction in inflation was probably the concurrent granting of independence to central banks which hitherto had been part of the finance ministries. Interestingly, a recent ECB Working Paper (”Global Inflation”) finds that one common factor accounts for 70% of the variance of inflation in industrial countries, inflation targeting or not.
Although inflation targeting is consistent and beautiful in theory, in practice, it suffers from serious shortcomings.
Sometime at the beginning of the 20th century, it was agreed that the most suitable measure of prices for monetary policy purposes is the consumer prices index. Consumer prices indeed have some attractive features: they directly affect most citizens, they are easy to gather, quickly available and are not revised. However, consumer prices are just a small subset of all prices in an economy, and therefore far from a comprehensive measure of “prices”. Not least Alchian and Klein (1973, “On a Correct Measure of Inflation”, JMCB) challenged (unsuccessfully) the use of consumer prices for monetary policy purposes.
The technical simplification soon took a life of it’s own, and in the minds of people, “consumer prices” became equivalent to “prices”. For example, most of today’s economics textbooks assume right from the start that the consumer price level is the one and only aggregate price level in an economy. People nowadays use the term inflation when in fact they mean consumer price inflation, the quantity theory of money is being (mis)interpreted such that money affects consumer prices, and Milton Friedman is (mis)understood as claiming that consumer price inflation is always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon.
Due to this subtle change of meaning, central banks, correctly wishing to provide price stability, wrongly restrict their focus on consumer prices. Unfortunately, money does not care about that change in semantics - it still affects all prices, including non-consumer goods prices, commodities, real estate, stocks, bonds and exchange rates. Not only has that been forgotten; central banks nowadays actually even deny responsibility for other prices than consumer prices.
In the face of a large positive supply shock from globalization, consumer prices should have been allowed to fall in recent years. By targeting a positive consumer price inflation rate, monetary policy has been too expansionary when it comes to other prices. Central banks have thus triggered a tsunami of liquidity and credit, which, probably some day soon, will come home to roost.
Don’t get me wrong: the idea of inflation targeting, namely stabilizing prices, is great. The original sin is the narrow focus on consumer prices. I don’t pretend to know how a better monetary policy strategy should look like. However, I suggest to look back into history for other viable monetary arrangements. Many clever people in the past must have had a reason when advocating to include monetary or credit aggregates into a monetary policy strategy, or to peg a currency to some asset which cannot be inflated at will, such as gold.
From: www.economicreason.com
Comment